Economy-Finance-Environment-Society Interconnections In a Stock-Flow Consistent Dynamic Model

IF 1.2 Q3 ECONOMICS
Emilio Carnevali, Matteo Deleidi, Riccardo Pariboni, Marco Veronese Passarella
{"title":"Economy-Finance-Environment-Society Interconnections In a Stock-Flow Consistent Dynamic Model","authors":"Emilio Carnevali, Matteo Deleidi, Riccardo Pariboni, Marco Veronese Passarella","doi":"10.1080/09538259.2023.2217776","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis work takes inspiration from four theoretical strands: recent developments in ecological macroeconomics; the Schumpeterian framework of evolutionary economics that emphasises the entrepreneurial role of the State; the stock-flow consistent approach to macroeconomic modelling; and the supermultiplier model. Building upon these approaches, we develop a formal model that reproduces key interactions between the economy, the financial sector, the ecosystem and the society. We test and assess the effects of several fiscal policies. We find that, in principle, mission-oriented innovation policies are the most effective option in supporting innovation and growth, while reducing income inequality. However, lacking a ‘green’ and progressive taxation system, they are unlikely to reverse the current trend in atmospheric temperature.KEYWORDS: Supermultipliermission-oriented policystock-flow consistent modellingclimate changerebound effectJEL CODES: B51B52E12Q57 AcknowledgementsWe would like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the editor and the reviewers for their feedback, which helped us improve our original draft and publish the article.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 There are a few exceptions, notably, Naqvi and Stockhammer (Citation2018) and Dafermos and Nikolaidi (Citation2019).2 Examples of MOIS policies include the Apollo Program (EC Citation2018a) and the Energiewende Programme (EC Citation2018b; Mazzucato Citation2018). The former is the US human spaceflight program carried out by the NASA, which led to the first manned landing on the moon in 1969. The latter is a German program aiming at reducing CO2 emissions by developing a low-carbon energy system at the national level. The main purpose of the Energiewende Programme is to allow Germany to stop energy production from nuclear plants by 2022, and to rely on renewable energy resources only by 2050. The program is expected to create favourable conditions for the private sector, offering new opportunities to undertake green technological innovation (thanks to government-financed investment activities).3 More precisely, ‘[p]ublic expenditure, exports, household residential investment, and consumption financed out of debt are considered autonomous components of aggregate demand in the literature and are the proximate cause of economic growth in the supermultiplier model. These components have two characteristics: they do not increase the (private) productive capacity of the economy and they are neither caused nor funded by domestic income’ (Morlin, Passos, and Pariboni Citation2022, p. 5).4 Recently, supermultiplier-like models have been used by economists with different theoretical backgrounds (e.g., Allain Citation2015; Lavoie Citation2016; Hein Citation2018; Fazzari, Ferri, and Variato Citation2020; Nomaler, Spinola, and Verspagen Citation2021).5 See, e.g., Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020); Morlin (Citation2022); Deleidi and Mazzucato (Citation2019, Citation2021); Nomaler, Spinola, and Verspagen (Citation2021).6 While firms' investment behaviour is more complex, we provide a stylized representation of capital accumulation in this article based on empirical literature that consistently finds a strong accelerator effect. A detailed analysis of this process is beyond the scope of this article.7 We maintain the same numbering of Appendix A, where the complete set of equations is reported.8 Adaptive expectations are assumed in our model. See equation (158) in Appendix A. For the sake of simplicity, we assume that ψ=0 in our simulations, so that: E(pw)=pw,−1.9 See Brochier and Macedo e Silva (Citation2019) for a similar approach.10 See equations (131) to (136) in Appendix A.11 Notice that hybrid technologies — say, an engine using both fossil fuel and wind as energy sources — are simply considered as involving a third type of capital (with respect to fossil fuel — and wind-based engines).12 Equations (87) and (88) demonstrate that our model incorporates two distinct sources of autonomous demand. In this way, our contribution aligns with recent works that analyse the sub-components of autonomous demand, rather than treating it as a single entity. For example, Hein and Woodgate (Citation2021) explore government spending and autonomous consumption, while Morlin (Citation2022) examines exports and government spending. In Allain (Citation2022) the two types of expenditure are not specified, while Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020) focus on government and autonomous capitalists' consumption, and Pedrosa, Brochier, and Freitas (Citation2021) analyze government and household consumption.13 We refer to Moretti, Steinwender, and Van Reenen (Citation2015), Deleidi, Mazzucato, and Semieniuk (Citation2020), Ciaffi and Deleidi (Citation2021), and Deleidi and Mazzucato (Citation2021) for empirical analyses of the impact of government MOIS on private R&D spending. Furthermore, we refer to Ciaffi and Deleidi (Citation2021) and Deleidi and Mazzucato (Citation2021) for the empirical literature showing that MOIS produces larger multiplicative effects on GDP than more standard government expenditures.14 The socio-economic stock is made up of capital goods and durable (or yet-to-be-discarded) consumption goods.15 Private investment is not directly influenced by matter and energy prices instead. However, there is an indirect effect, for changes in prices affect the rates of extraction (or use) of natural reserves. These rates, in turn, affect the price level, real output, hence investment decisions.16 See equations (154) to (157) in Appendix A.17 Simulations have been performed using EViews. We are happy to provide the programming code.18 We refer to Carnevali et al. (Citation2021), who use an open-economy ecological SFC model prototype to analyse cross-border policy coordination problems.19 Notice also that LC households are usually assumed to have a higher propensity to consume relative to UC households. However, their consumption is usually greener, as green intentions of the upper classes are crowded out by wealth. In other words, ecological impacts are best predicted by people’s income level (e.g., Moser and Kleinhückelkotten Citation2018). As a result, the change in emissions due to policy (b) relative to policy (a) is ambiguous.20 See notes under Table 4 for further details.21 We refer the reader to equations (34) and (35), defining household debt level and ratio, respectively.22 Income inequality is measured as UC household income (including capital gains) to total income after taxes. Similarly, wealth inequality is measured as UC household net wealth to total net wealth.23 The same experiment can be replicated using alternative variables and/or composite indices for the four main spheres of our artificial world.","PeriodicalId":46174,"journal":{"name":"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY","volume":"13 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-09-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2023.2217776","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

ABSTRACTThis work takes inspiration from four theoretical strands: recent developments in ecological macroeconomics; the Schumpeterian framework of evolutionary economics that emphasises the entrepreneurial role of the State; the stock-flow consistent approach to macroeconomic modelling; and the supermultiplier model. Building upon these approaches, we develop a formal model that reproduces key interactions between the economy, the financial sector, the ecosystem and the society. We test and assess the effects of several fiscal policies. We find that, in principle, mission-oriented innovation policies are the most effective option in supporting innovation and growth, while reducing income inequality. However, lacking a ‘green’ and progressive taxation system, they are unlikely to reverse the current trend in atmospheric temperature.KEYWORDS: Supermultipliermission-oriented policystock-flow consistent modellingclimate changerebound effectJEL CODES: B51B52E12Q57 AcknowledgementsWe would like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the editor and the reviewers for their feedback, which helped us improve our original draft and publish the article.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 There are a few exceptions, notably, Naqvi and Stockhammer (Citation2018) and Dafermos and Nikolaidi (Citation2019).2 Examples of MOIS policies include the Apollo Program (EC Citation2018a) and the Energiewende Programme (EC Citation2018b; Mazzucato Citation2018). The former is the US human spaceflight program carried out by the NASA, which led to the first manned landing on the moon in 1969. The latter is a German program aiming at reducing CO2 emissions by developing a low-carbon energy system at the national level. The main purpose of the Energiewende Programme is to allow Germany to stop energy production from nuclear plants by 2022, and to rely on renewable energy resources only by 2050. The program is expected to create favourable conditions for the private sector, offering new opportunities to undertake green technological innovation (thanks to government-financed investment activities).3 More precisely, ‘[p]ublic expenditure, exports, household residential investment, and consumption financed out of debt are considered autonomous components of aggregate demand in the literature and are the proximate cause of economic growth in the supermultiplier model. These components have two characteristics: they do not increase the (private) productive capacity of the economy and they are neither caused nor funded by domestic income’ (Morlin, Passos, and Pariboni Citation2022, p. 5).4 Recently, supermultiplier-like models have been used by economists with different theoretical backgrounds (e.g., Allain Citation2015; Lavoie Citation2016; Hein Citation2018; Fazzari, Ferri, and Variato Citation2020; Nomaler, Spinola, and Verspagen Citation2021).5 See, e.g., Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020); Morlin (Citation2022); Deleidi and Mazzucato (Citation2019, Citation2021); Nomaler, Spinola, and Verspagen (Citation2021).6 While firms' investment behaviour is more complex, we provide a stylized representation of capital accumulation in this article based on empirical literature that consistently finds a strong accelerator effect. A detailed analysis of this process is beyond the scope of this article.7 We maintain the same numbering of Appendix A, where the complete set of equations is reported.8 Adaptive expectations are assumed in our model. See equation (158) in Appendix A. For the sake of simplicity, we assume that ψ=0 in our simulations, so that: E(pw)=pw,−1.9 See Brochier and Macedo e Silva (Citation2019) for a similar approach.10 See equations (131) to (136) in Appendix A.11 Notice that hybrid technologies — say, an engine using both fossil fuel and wind as energy sources — are simply considered as involving a third type of capital (with respect to fossil fuel — and wind-based engines).12 Equations (87) and (88) demonstrate that our model incorporates two distinct sources of autonomous demand. In this way, our contribution aligns with recent works that analyse the sub-components of autonomous demand, rather than treating it as a single entity. For example, Hein and Woodgate (Citation2021) explore government spending and autonomous consumption, while Morlin (Citation2022) examines exports and government spending. In Allain (Citation2022) the two types of expenditure are not specified, while Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020) focus on government and autonomous capitalists' consumption, and Pedrosa, Brochier, and Freitas (Citation2021) analyze government and household consumption.13 We refer to Moretti, Steinwender, and Van Reenen (Citation2015), Deleidi, Mazzucato, and Semieniuk (Citation2020), Ciaffi and Deleidi (Citation2021), and Deleidi and Mazzucato (Citation2021) for empirical analyses of the impact of government MOIS on private R&D spending. Furthermore, we refer to Ciaffi and Deleidi (Citation2021) and Deleidi and Mazzucato (Citation2021) for the empirical literature showing that MOIS produces larger multiplicative effects on GDP than more standard government expenditures.14 The socio-economic stock is made up of capital goods and durable (or yet-to-be-discarded) consumption goods.15 Private investment is not directly influenced by matter and energy prices instead. However, there is an indirect effect, for changes in prices affect the rates of extraction (or use) of natural reserves. These rates, in turn, affect the price level, real output, hence investment decisions.16 See equations (154) to (157) in Appendix A.17 Simulations have been performed using EViews. We are happy to provide the programming code.18 We refer to Carnevali et al. (Citation2021), who use an open-economy ecological SFC model prototype to analyse cross-border policy coordination problems.19 Notice also that LC households are usually assumed to have a higher propensity to consume relative to UC households. However, their consumption is usually greener, as green intentions of the upper classes are crowded out by wealth. In other words, ecological impacts are best predicted by people’s income level (e.g., Moser and Kleinhückelkotten Citation2018). As a result, the change in emissions due to policy (b) relative to policy (a) is ambiguous.20 See notes under Table 4 for further details.21 We refer the reader to equations (34) and (35), defining household debt level and ratio, respectively.22 Income inequality is measured as UC household income (including capital gains) to total income after taxes. Similarly, wealth inequality is measured as UC household net wealth to total net wealth.23 The same experiment can be replicated using alternative variables and/or composite indices for the four main spheres of our artificial world.
存量-流量一致动态模型中的经济-金融-环境-社会联系
此外,我们参考了Ciaffi和Deleidi (Citation2021)以及Deleidi和Mazzucato (Citation2021)的实证文献,这些文献表明MOIS比更标准的政府支出对GDP产生更大的乘数效应社会经济存量由资本品和耐用消费品(或尚未被丢弃的消费品)组成私人投资并不直接受到物质和能源价格的影响。然而,有一种间接影响,因为价格的变化会影响自然储备的开采(或利用)速度。这些利率反过来又影响价格水平、实际产出,从而影响投资决策参见附录A.17中的公式(154)至(157),使用EViews进行了模拟。我们很乐意提供编程代码我们参考了Carnevali等人(Citation2021),他们使用开放经济生态SFC模型原型来分析跨境政策协调问题还请注意,LC家庭通常被认为相对于UC家庭具有更高的消费倾向。然而,他们的消费通常更环保,因为上层阶级的环保意图被财富所排挤。换句话说,生态影响最好通过人们的收入水平来预测(例如,Moser和kleinhckelkotten Citation2018)。因此,政策(b)相对于政策(a)造成的排放量变化是含糊不清的详情见表4下的说明我们请读者参考公式(34)和式(35),分别定义了家庭债务水平和比率收入不平等是衡量UC家庭收入(包括资本收益)的税后总收入。同样,财富不平等是用UC家庭净财富与总净财富之比来衡量的同样的实验可以在我们人工世界的四个主要领域中使用替代变量和/或复合指数来复制。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
2.60
自引率
20.00%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: The Review of Political Economy is a peer-reviewed journal welcoming constructive and critical contributions in all areas of political economy, including the Austrian, Behavioral Economics, Feminist Economics, Institutionalist, Marxian, Post Keynesian, and Sraffian traditions. The Review publishes both theoretical and empirical research, and is also open to submissions in methodology, economic history and the history of economic thought that cast light on issues of contemporary relevance in political economy. Comments on articles published in the Review are encouraged.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信