Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism by Dara Orenstein (review)

Arris Pub Date : 2023-01-01 DOI:10.1353/arr.2023.a909928
Patrick Haughey
{"title":"Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism by Dara Orenstein (review)","authors":"Patrick Haughey","doi":"10.1353/arr.2023.a909928","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Reviewed by: Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism by Dara Orenstein Patrick Haughey Dara Orenstein. Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2019. Hardcover ISBN: 9780226662879 Paperback ISBN: 9780226662909 Ebook ISBN: 9780226663067 Paperback: 340 pages Illustrations: 93 black-and-white In the United States, manufacturing as a percentage of gross domestic product peaked just after World War II. By the 1980s, cities had emptied out. While many attribute this transformation to white flight, urban renewal, and segregated housing laws, Dara Orenstein’s Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism adds an important twist to the story. In 1934, under the leadership of President Franklin D. Roosevelt, the United States began creating foreign free trade ports. Since then, entire sections of ports within the nation’s borders have been zoned out of paying taxes and rules governing trade. This legal and territorial tax freedom gave corporate interests a way to outsource jobs while remaining onshore. As Orenstein writes, “Out of Stock describes a global phenomenon, but not in the manner . . . that recounts the quantifiable, immediate effects of Walmart, or guns, butter, and steel. . . . Taking stock of the zone helps us to divine how economic processes are territorialized” (19). Out of Stock chronicles the history of free trade zones in the United States and their role in the history of global capitalism. The title of the book is misleading. Although Orenstein traces the roots of free-trade zones to bonded warehouses, a nineteenth-century innovation that temporarily suspended duties on imported goods, the book is not a history of warehouses as a form of storage or an architectural type. Rather, Orenstein is concerned with warehousing as a system of storing goods in motion—that is, as they move through the economy—for commercial gain. This view matches the definition that developed within the warehousing industry after the Civil War and emphasizes the role of warehousing in the circulation of financial capital. Extended to free-trade zones, it highlights the supposedly frictionless dimensions of extraterritorial spaces freed from barriers to trade imposed by the nation-state. Out of Stock begins its analysis in 1789, the year Congress passed legislation refunding tariffs on imports if manufacturers used those imports to produce exports. The story really picks up after the Civil War, however. As American manufacturing expanded by leaps and bounds, warehousing became central to the circulation of commodities in the marketplace and a highly profitable business. Orenstein traces the history of merchants’ and manufacturers’ efforts to avoid duties and tariffs and to circumvent territorial barriers, introducing readers to free ports, bonded warehouses, customs unions, and a host of technical innovations. All of these measures sought to increase trading efficiency but invariably ran into political wrangling, protectionism, international conflicts, and national governments’ thirst for revenue. In 1934, Congress passed the Foreign-Trade Zones Act. This legislation responded to the economic crisis of the Great Depression by authorizing foreign-trade zones at US ports. In an immediate sense, it sought to stimulate international trade. As Orenstein shows, however, it marked the beginning of what has become the largest zone system in the world. Supervised by the US Department of Commerce, zones allowed for the duty-free circulation of goods provided no manufacturing or exhibiting occurred. Considered experimental at the time, they developed slowly. The first began operating on Staten Island in 1937. Others followed at New Orleans, San Francisco, and Seattle. In 1950, Congress amended the act to create subzones—tariff-free spaces detached from waterfronts that permitted manufacturing and exhibiting. The concept was slow to take [End Page 69] hold; the Department of Commerce did not authorize the first subzone until 1962. Yet, as Orenstein shows, they proliferated in the 1970s and 1980s as corporations sought not only to avoid tariffs but to take advantage of wage differentials and non-union labor. Why did Nissan begin manufacturing pickup trucks and sedans outside of Nashville in the early 1980s? Subzone 78A and the much lower tariffs it offered. In 1965, the United States had eight general-purpose zones and three subzones. By 1989, those numbers had grown to 164 and 181...","PeriodicalId":478414,"journal":{"name":"Arris","volume":"141 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2023-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Arris","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1353/arr.2023.a909928","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Reviewed by: Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism by Dara Orenstein Patrick Haughey Dara Orenstein. Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2019. Hardcover ISBN: 9780226662879 Paperback ISBN: 9780226662909 Ebook ISBN: 9780226663067 Paperback: 340 pages Illustrations: 93 black-and-white In the United States, manufacturing as a percentage of gross domestic product peaked just after World War II. By the 1980s, cities had emptied out. While many attribute this transformation to white flight, urban renewal, and segregated housing laws, Dara Orenstein’s Out of Stock: The Warehouse in the History of Capitalism adds an important twist to the story. In 1934, under the leadership of President Franklin D. Roosevelt, the United States began creating foreign free trade ports. Since then, entire sections of ports within the nation’s borders have been zoned out of paying taxes and rules governing trade. This legal and territorial tax freedom gave corporate interests a way to outsource jobs while remaining onshore. As Orenstein writes, “Out of Stock describes a global phenomenon, but not in the manner . . . that recounts the quantifiable, immediate effects of Walmart, or guns, butter, and steel. . . . Taking stock of the zone helps us to divine how economic processes are territorialized” (19). Out of Stock chronicles the history of free trade zones in the United States and their role in the history of global capitalism. The title of the book is misleading. Although Orenstein traces the roots of free-trade zones to bonded warehouses, a nineteenth-century innovation that temporarily suspended duties on imported goods, the book is not a history of warehouses as a form of storage or an architectural type. Rather, Orenstein is concerned with warehousing as a system of storing goods in motion—that is, as they move through the economy—for commercial gain. This view matches the definition that developed within the warehousing industry after the Civil War and emphasizes the role of warehousing in the circulation of financial capital. Extended to free-trade zones, it highlights the supposedly frictionless dimensions of extraterritorial spaces freed from barriers to trade imposed by the nation-state. Out of Stock begins its analysis in 1789, the year Congress passed legislation refunding tariffs on imports if manufacturers used those imports to produce exports. The story really picks up after the Civil War, however. As American manufacturing expanded by leaps and bounds, warehousing became central to the circulation of commodities in the marketplace and a highly profitable business. Orenstein traces the history of merchants’ and manufacturers’ efforts to avoid duties and tariffs and to circumvent territorial barriers, introducing readers to free ports, bonded warehouses, customs unions, and a host of technical innovations. All of these measures sought to increase trading efficiency but invariably ran into political wrangling, protectionism, international conflicts, and national governments’ thirst for revenue. In 1934, Congress passed the Foreign-Trade Zones Act. This legislation responded to the economic crisis of the Great Depression by authorizing foreign-trade zones at US ports. In an immediate sense, it sought to stimulate international trade. As Orenstein shows, however, it marked the beginning of what has become the largest zone system in the world. Supervised by the US Department of Commerce, zones allowed for the duty-free circulation of goods provided no manufacturing or exhibiting occurred. Considered experimental at the time, they developed slowly. The first began operating on Staten Island in 1937. Others followed at New Orleans, San Francisco, and Seattle. In 1950, Congress amended the act to create subzones—tariff-free spaces detached from waterfronts that permitted manufacturing and exhibiting. The concept was slow to take [End Page 69] hold; the Department of Commerce did not authorize the first subzone until 1962. Yet, as Orenstein shows, they proliferated in the 1970s and 1980s as corporations sought not only to avoid tariffs but to take advantage of wage differentials and non-union labor. Why did Nissan begin manufacturing pickup trucks and sedans outside of Nashville in the early 1980s? Subzone 78A and the much lower tariffs it offered. In 1965, the United States had eight general-purpose zones and three subzones. By 1989, those numbers had grown to 164 and 181...
《缺货:资本主义历史上的仓库》达拉·奥伦斯坦著(书评)
书评:《缺货:资本主义历史上的仓库》作者:达拉·奥伦斯坦缺货:资本主义历史上的仓库。芝加哥:芝加哥大学出版社,2019。精装ISBN: 9780226662909电子书ISBN: 9780226663067平装:340页插图:93黑白在美国,制造业占国内生产总值的百分比在第二次世界大战后达到顶峰。到20世纪80年代,城市已经清空。1934年,在富兰克林·罗斯福总统的领导下,美国开始创建外国自由贸易港。从那时起,该国境内的整个港口都被划为禁区,不纳税,也不遵守贸易管理规则。这种法律上和地域上的税收自由,为企业提供了一种将工作外包、同时留在国内的方式。正如奥伦斯坦所写,“缺货描述的是一种全球现象,但方式不同……它讲述了沃尔玛或枪支、黄油和钢铁的可量化的直接影响. . . .对区域进行评估有助于我们预测经济进程是如何被领土化的”(19)。《脱销》记录了美国自由贸易区的历史及其在全球资本主义历史中的作用。这本书的书名令人误解。虽然奥伦斯坦将自由贸易区的根源追溯到保税仓库,这是19世纪的一项创新,它暂时取消了进口商品的关税,但这本书并不是一部关于仓库作为一种存储形式或一种建筑类型的历史。相反,奥伦斯坦关注的是仓储作为一种储存运动中的货物的系统——也就是说,当货物在经济中移动时——以获得商业利益。这一观点与内战后仓储业内部发展的定义相吻合,强调仓储在金融资本流通中的作用。延伸到自由贸易区,它突出了所谓的无摩擦的域外空间维度,从民族国家强加的贸易壁垒中解放出来。《缺货》的分析开始于1789年,这一年国会通过了一项法案,如果制造商使用这些进口产品生产出口产品,就退还进口关税。然而,故事真正开始于南北战争之后。随着美国制造业突飞猛进的发展,仓储成为市场上商品流通的核心,成为一项高利润的业务。奥伦斯坦追溯了商人和制造商努力避免关税和规避领土壁垒的历史,向读者介绍了自由港、保税仓库、关税同盟和大量技术创新。所有这些措施都是为了提高贸易效率,但无一例外地遇到了政治角力、保护主义、国际冲突和各国政府对收入的渴望。1934年,国会通过了《对外贸易区法案》。这项立法通过授权在美国港口设立对外贸易区来应对大萧条的经济危机。从直接意义上说,它寻求刺激国际贸易。然而,正如奥伦斯坦所表明的那样,它标志着世界上最大的区域体系的开始。在美国商务部的监管下,只要没有制造或展览活动,就允许免税商品流通。当时被认为是实验性的,它们发展缓慢。第一艘船于1937年在斯塔顿岛开始运营。紧随其后的是新奥尔良、旧金山和西雅图。1950年,国会对该法案进行了修订,创建了分区——与海滨分离的免税空间,允许制造和展览。这个概念被慢慢接受;商务部直到1962年才批准设立第一个分区。然而,正如奥伦斯坦所表明的那样,在20世纪70年代和80年代,随着企业不仅寻求避免关税,而且利用工资差异和非工会劳工,这种做法激增。为什么尼桑在20世纪80年代初开始在纳什维尔以外的地方生产皮卡和轿车?78A分区及其提供的低得多的关税。1965年,美国有8个通用区和3个分区。到1989年,这两个数字分别增长到164和181。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信