Twist and shout, or back to the sixties

James Bullard
{"title":"Twist and shout, or back to the sixties","authors":"James Bullard","doi":"10.20955/es.2005.7","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has increased the target federal funds rate at each meeting since June 2004, to 2.5 percent following the February 2005 meeting. A puzzling aspect of recent financial market developments has been that, despite the rise of 150 basis points in the Fed’s target rate, longer-term rates have remained roughly constant. In recent testimony, Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan commented extensively on this issue, eventually concluding that the market behavior “remains a conundrum.”1 There was a time when this same behavior would not have been considered so unusual. It occurred in the early 1960s, a cherished era among monetary economists and policymakers. That era sported relatively rapid growth in both real output and productivity, low inflation rates, and low rates of interest, not unlike the present day. Although many years have passed since that time, the intervening years have been associated with higher inflation—at times substantially higher—and have been dominated by Federal Reserve efforts to move inflation lower and build credibility for continued low inflation. The low level of inflation and high level of Fed credibility characteristic of the early 1960s returned in the early 2000s. Thus, the early 1960s may give a better indication of the nature of today’s financial markets than most of the intervening years. The chart shows the evolution of shortand longerterm interest rates during the 38 months following the last month of the recession relevant to each era. The most recent recession ended in November 2001, while for the earlier era it ended in February 1961. The chart shows the effective federal funds rate along with the longer-term 10-year Treasury note yield. The most striking characteristic is that in both eras, once the federal funds rate began rising following the recession, the longer-term bond yield remained anchored near 4 percent. One explanation is that, in both eras, the private sector viewed movements in short-term interest rates as exactly those necessary to keep inflation low and steady, so that longer-term inflation expectations and hence longer-term bond yields could remain anchored. Similarities in the interest rate environment may also be attributable in part to similarities in economic performance. The average annualized quarterly growth rates of key variables were a lot alike during 2002:Q1 to 2004:Q4 as compared with the corresponding 1961:Q2 to 1964:Q4 period. Average nonfarm business sector productivity growth, for instance, was almost identical during the two periods, 3.90 percent today versus 3.80 percent in the early 1960s. Inflation rates were similar as well, with the core consumer price index increasing, on average, 1.80 percent during the current period versus 1.40 percent during the earlier era. Real output growth was robust in both periods as well, 3.50 percent in the early 2000s versus 5.40 percent in the early 1960s. The expansion of the 1960s was one of the longest on record, lasting until December 1969, when a relatively mild recession occurred. Inflation began to rise unexpectedly during the last half of the 1960s, setting the stage for the economically volatile decade to follow. Whether today’s FOMC will manage a 1960s-style expansion remains to be seen, but the era may be a good one to learn from given the similar levels of inflation and Fed credibility.","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"National Economic Trends","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2005.7","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has increased the target federal funds rate at each meeting since June 2004, to 2.5 percent following the February 2005 meeting. A puzzling aspect of recent financial market developments has been that, despite the rise of 150 basis points in the Fed’s target rate, longer-term rates have remained roughly constant. In recent testimony, Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan commented extensively on this issue, eventually concluding that the market behavior “remains a conundrum.”1 There was a time when this same behavior would not have been considered so unusual. It occurred in the early 1960s, a cherished era among monetary economists and policymakers. That era sported relatively rapid growth in both real output and productivity, low inflation rates, and low rates of interest, not unlike the present day. Although many years have passed since that time, the intervening years have been associated with higher inflation—at times substantially higher—and have been dominated by Federal Reserve efforts to move inflation lower and build credibility for continued low inflation. The low level of inflation and high level of Fed credibility characteristic of the early 1960s returned in the early 2000s. Thus, the early 1960s may give a better indication of the nature of today’s financial markets than most of the intervening years. The chart shows the evolution of shortand longerterm interest rates during the 38 months following the last month of the recession relevant to each era. The most recent recession ended in November 2001, while for the earlier era it ended in February 1961. The chart shows the effective federal funds rate along with the longer-term 10-year Treasury note yield. The most striking characteristic is that in both eras, once the federal funds rate began rising following the recession, the longer-term bond yield remained anchored near 4 percent. One explanation is that, in both eras, the private sector viewed movements in short-term interest rates as exactly those necessary to keep inflation low and steady, so that longer-term inflation expectations and hence longer-term bond yields could remain anchored. Similarities in the interest rate environment may also be attributable in part to similarities in economic performance. The average annualized quarterly growth rates of key variables were a lot alike during 2002:Q1 to 2004:Q4 as compared with the corresponding 1961:Q2 to 1964:Q4 period. Average nonfarm business sector productivity growth, for instance, was almost identical during the two periods, 3.90 percent today versus 3.80 percent in the early 1960s. Inflation rates were similar as well, with the core consumer price index increasing, on average, 1.80 percent during the current period versus 1.40 percent during the earlier era. Real output growth was robust in both periods as well, 3.50 percent in the early 2000s versus 5.40 percent in the early 1960s. The expansion of the 1960s was one of the longest on record, lasting until December 1969, when a relatively mild recession occurred. Inflation began to rise unexpectedly during the last half of the 1960s, setting the stage for the economically volatile decade to follow. Whether today’s FOMC will manage a 1960s-style expansion remains to be seen, but the era may be a good one to learn from given the similar levels of inflation and Fed credibility.
扭来扭去喊去,不然就回到六十年代
本文所表达的观点不一定反映联邦储备系统的官方立场。自2004年6月以来,联邦公开市场委员会(FOMC)在每次会议上都将联邦基金目标利率上调,2005年2月会议后上调至2.5%。最近金融市场发展的一个令人困惑的方面是,尽管美联储的目标利率上升了150个基点,但长期利率却基本保持不变。在最近的证词中,美联储主席艾伦·格林斯潘(Alan Greenspan)对这个问题发表了广泛的评论,最终得出结论,市场行为“仍然是一个难题”。在过去,这种行为并不会被认为是不寻常的。它发生在20世纪60年代初,这是货币经济学家和政策制定者所珍视的时代。那个时代的实际产出和生产率增长相对较快,通货膨胀率较低,利率也较低,与今天没有什么不同。尽管从那时起已经过去了许多年,但其间的几年一直伴随着更高的通胀——有时高得多——美联储一直在努力降低通胀,并为持续的低通胀建立信誉。上世纪60年代初的低通胀水平和美联储高可信度特征在本世纪初重现。因此,20世纪60年代早期可能比中间的大多数年份更能说明当今金融市场的性质。该图显示了与每个时代相关的衰退最后一个月后的38个月内短期和长期利率的演变。最近一次衰退结束于2001年11月,而前一次衰退结束于1961年2月。该图显示了有效联邦基金利率以及长期10年期美国国债收益率。最显著的特征是,在这两个时期,一旦联邦基金利率在衰退后开始上升,长期债券收益率仍稳定在4%附近。一种解释是,在这两个时代,私人部门都认为短期利率的变动正是保持低通胀和稳定所必需的,这样长期通胀预期和长期债券收益率才能保持稳定。利率环境的相似也可能部分归因于经济表现的相似。在2002年第一季度至2004年第四季度期间,关键变量的平均年化季度增长率与相应的1961年第二季度至1964年第四季度期间非常相似。例如,在这两个时期,非农部门的平均生产率增长几乎相同,今天是3.90%,而上世纪60年代初是3.80%。通货膨胀率也相似,核心消费者价格指数平均上涨,当前时期为1.80%,而早先时期为1.40%。这两个时期的实际产出增长都很强劲,21世纪初为3.50%,而20世纪60年代初为5.40%。20世纪60年代的经济扩张是有记录以来持续时间最长的一次,一直持续到1969年12月,当时出现了一场相对温和的衰退。在20世纪60年代后半期,通货膨胀开始意外上升,为接下来动荡的十年经济埋下了伏笔。今天的联邦公开市场委员会是否会像上世纪60年代那样实现扩张还有待观察,但考虑到类似的通胀水平和美联储的可信度,这个时代可能是一个值得学习的好时代。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信