Discovery as Regulation

Diego A. Zambrano
{"title":"Discovery as Regulation","authors":"Diego A. Zambrano","doi":"10.36644/MLR.119.1.DISCOVERY","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"This article develops an approach to discovery that is grounded in regulatory theory and administrative subpoena power. The conventional judicial and scholarly view about discovery is that it promotes fair and accurate outcomes and nudges the parties towards settlement. While commonly held, however, this belief is increasingly outdated and suffers from limitations. Among them, it has generated endless controversy about the problem of discovery costs. Indeed, a growing chorus of scholars and courts have offered an avalanche of reforms, from cost shifting and bespoke discovery contracts to outright elimination. Recently, Judge Thomas Hardiman quipped that if he had absolute power he would abolish discovery for cases involving less than $500,000. These debates, however, are at a standstill and existing scholarship offers incomplete treatment of discovery theory that might move debates forward. \n \nThe core insight of the project is that in the private enforcement context — where Congress deliberately employs private litigants as the main method of statutory enforcement — there is a surprisingly strong case that our current discovery system should be understood in part as serving regulatory goals analogous to administrative subpoena power. That is, discovery here can be seen as an extension of the subpoena power that agencies like the SEC, FTC, and EPA possess and is the lynchpin of a system that depends on private litigants to enforce our most important statutes. By forcing parties to disclose large amounts of information, discovery deters harm and, most importantly, shapes industry-wide practices and the primary behavior of regulated entities. This approach has a vast array of implications for the scope of discovery as well as the debate over costs. Scholars and courts should thus grapple with the consequences of what I call “regulatory discovery” for the entire legal system.","PeriodicalId":344388,"journal":{"name":"Law & Society: Civil Procedure eJournal","volume":"20 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2019-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"4","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Law & Society: Civil Procedure eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.36644/MLR.119.1.DISCOVERY","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4

Abstract

This article develops an approach to discovery that is grounded in regulatory theory and administrative subpoena power. The conventional judicial and scholarly view about discovery is that it promotes fair and accurate outcomes and nudges the parties towards settlement. While commonly held, however, this belief is increasingly outdated and suffers from limitations. Among them, it has generated endless controversy about the problem of discovery costs. Indeed, a growing chorus of scholars and courts have offered an avalanche of reforms, from cost shifting and bespoke discovery contracts to outright elimination. Recently, Judge Thomas Hardiman quipped that if he had absolute power he would abolish discovery for cases involving less than $500,000. These debates, however, are at a standstill and existing scholarship offers incomplete treatment of discovery theory that might move debates forward. The core insight of the project is that in the private enforcement context — where Congress deliberately employs private litigants as the main method of statutory enforcement — there is a surprisingly strong case that our current discovery system should be understood in part as serving regulatory goals analogous to administrative subpoena power. That is, discovery here can be seen as an extension of the subpoena power that agencies like the SEC, FTC, and EPA possess and is the lynchpin of a system that depends on private litigants to enforce our most important statutes. By forcing parties to disclose large amounts of information, discovery deters harm and, most importantly, shapes industry-wide practices and the primary behavior of regulated entities. This approach has a vast array of implications for the scope of discovery as well as the debate over costs. Scholars and courts should thus grapple with the consequences of what I call “regulatory discovery” for the entire legal system.
发现即规则
本文发展了一种以监管理论和行政传票权为基础的发现方法。传统的司法和学术对证据开示的看法是,它促进了公正和准确的结果,并推动各方达成和解。然而,尽管人们普遍持有这种观点,但这种观点越来越过时,而且受到限制。其中,关于发现成本的问题引发了无休止的争论。事实上,越来越多的学者和法院已经提出了大量的改革,从成本转移和定制的发现合同到彻底取消。最近,法官托马斯·哈迪曼(Thomas Hardiman)打趣说,如果他拥有绝对的权力,他会废除涉及不到50万美元的案件的证据开证。然而,这些辩论处于停滞状态,现有的学术研究对发现理论提供了不完整的处理,这可能会推动辩论向前发展。该项目的核心观点是,在私人执法的背景下——国会故意使用私人诉讼作为法定执法的主要方法——有一个令人惊讶的强有力的案例,我们目前的发现制度应该被理解为部分服务于类似于行政传票权力的监管目标。也就是说,在这里,证据开证可以被视为证交会、联邦贸易委员会和环境保护局等机构所拥有的传讯权力的延伸,是一个依靠私人诉讼当事人来执行我们最重要法规的制度的关键。通过迫使当事人披露大量信息,信息发现阻止了伤害,最重要的是,它塑造了整个行业的惯例和受监管实体的主要行为。这种方法对发现的范围和成本的争论有着广泛的影响。因此,学者和法院应该努力解决我所谓的“监管发现”对整个法律体系的影响。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信