Comment

Michael McMahon
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Michael McMahon","doi":"10.1086/658312","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"One of the recent major debates in macroeconomics concerns the role of technology shocks that play a major role in the standard real business cycle (RBC) model. One aspect of this debate concerns the response of hours to technology shocks. Galí’s (1999) empirical evidence concluded that the technology shock was not a key driver of the business cycle and cast doubt on the RBC modeling paradigm. Galí identified the effects of technology shocks using an estimated vector autoregression (VAR) that relied on the identification mechanism that only technology shocks have a permanent effect on labor productivity; this assumption is justified by the main RBC andNewKeynesian models. He finds that hours worked fall in response to a positive technology shock; the negative correlation between labor input and output contradicts the prediction of both the RBC model and the empirical data of a positive correlation. Since it was first published in 1999 (having been earlier released as a working paper in 1996), this “TFP ↑ ⇒ hours ↓” finding has created a great deal of discussion. Other authors such as Francis and Ramey (2005) and Basu, Fernald, and Kimball (2006) endorse the finding of Galí. The former paper carries out a number of robustness checks on the identified technology shocks, whereas the latter uses an entirely different methodology to identify the technology shocks. Both corroborate the TFP ↑ ⇒ hours ↓ finding of Galí. There have been twomain angles of attack on this finding: one concerns the low-frequency properties of the hours data series, and the other considers the identification assumption in the Galí work. This latter approach suggests that other factorsmay affect productivity in the long run. One example of the approach that questions the identification strategy is the article by Fisher (2006). Fisher allows for both traditional technological","PeriodicalId":353207,"journal":{"name":"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2011-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1086/658312","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

One of the recent major debates in macroeconomics concerns the role of technology shocks that play a major role in the standard real business cycle (RBC) model. One aspect of this debate concerns the response of hours to technology shocks. Galí’s (1999) empirical evidence concluded that the technology shock was not a key driver of the business cycle and cast doubt on the RBC modeling paradigm. Galí identified the effects of technology shocks using an estimated vector autoregression (VAR) that relied on the identification mechanism that only technology shocks have a permanent effect on labor productivity; this assumption is justified by the main RBC andNewKeynesian models. He finds that hours worked fall in response to a positive technology shock; the negative correlation between labor input and output contradicts the prediction of both the RBC model and the empirical data of a positive correlation. Since it was first published in 1999 (having been earlier released as a working paper in 1996), this “TFP ↑ ⇒ hours ↓” finding has created a great deal of discussion. Other authors such as Francis and Ramey (2005) and Basu, Fernald, and Kimball (2006) endorse the finding of Galí. The former paper carries out a number of robustness checks on the identified technology shocks, whereas the latter uses an entirely different methodology to identify the technology shocks. Both corroborate the TFP ↑ ⇒ hours ↓ finding of Galí. There have been twomain angles of attack on this finding: one concerns the low-frequency properties of the hours data series, and the other considers the identification assumption in the Galí work. This latter approach suggests that other factorsmay affect productivity in the long run. One example of the approach that questions the identification strategy is the article by Fisher (2006). Fisher allows for both traditional technological
评论
最近宏观经济学的主要争论之一是技术冲击在标准实际商业周期(RBC)模型中扮演的重要角色。这场辩论的一个方面涉及对技术冲击的反应。Galí(1999)的经验证据得出结论,技术冲击不是商业周期的关键驱动因素,并对RBC模型范式提出质疑。Galí使用估计向量自回归(VAR)识别技术冲击的影响,该识别机制依赖于只有技术冲击对劳动生产率有永久影响的识别机制;RBC和新凯恩斯主义的主要模型证实了这一假设。他发现,在积极的技术冲击下,工作时间会缩短;劳动投入与产出的负相关关系与RBC模型的预测和实证数据的正相关关系相矛盾。自1999年首次发表以来(早在1996年作为工作论文发布),这一“TFP↑⇒hours↓”的发现就引发了大量讨论。其他作者如Francis和Ramey(2005)以及Basu、Fernald和Kimball(2006)支持Galí的发现。前一篇论文对识别的技术冲击进行了大量的鲁棒性检查,而后者使用了一种完全不同的方法来识别技术冲击。两者都证实了Galí的TFP↑⇒hours↓发现。对这一发现有两个主要的攻击角度:一个涉及小时数据系列的低频特性,另一个考虑Galí工作中的识别假设。后一种方法表明,从长远来看,其他因素可能会影响生产率。质疑识别策略的方法的一个例子是Fisher(2006)的文章。费雪同时考虑了传统技术
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信