Is U.S. CEO Compensation Inefficient Pay Without Performance?

J. Core, W. Guay, Randall S. Thomas
{"title":"Is U.S. CEO Compensation Inefficient Pay Without Performance?","authors":"J. Core, W. Guay, Randall S. Thomas","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.648648","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, we review Pay Without Performance by Professors Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried. The book develops and summarizes the leading critiques of current executive compensation practices in the U.S., and offers a negative, if mainstream, assessment of the state of U.S. executive compensation: U.S. executive compensation practices are failing, and systemic reform is needed. This review summarizes the book in some detail and offers some counter-arguments. The book's thesis is that executive compensation practices are bad for shareholders (not \"optimal\") because they are the product of \"managerial power.\" Managerial power arises because boards of directors at public companies are not independent of executives. Weak compensation committees thus do little to protect the firm in its pay negotiations with the CEO, leading to levels of executive pay that are both inappropriately high and have inappropriately low levels of incentives. The authors offer a four part analysis of CEO pay. First, they describe and critique optimal contracting theory, which posits that executive compensation arrangements are designed to benefit shareholders. Second, they explain managerial power theory, in part through an in-depth analysis of current executive compensation practices. They assert the managerial power theory provides a superior explanation of current practices to the optimal contracting perspective. They also draw the strong implication that if managerial power exists, it means that something is wrong with the contracting process. Third, they claim that CEO compensation does not vary sufficiently with firm performance. They conclude with policy recommendations for changing compensation plans and improving corporate governance, for example by requiring that directors be more independent. We agree that it is useful to consider the effect of managerial power on compensation, but we disagree with their interpretation of the consequences of this power. It is true that contract structures reflect CEO power, and that CEOs with more power get more pay, but this does not necessarily lead to the conclusion that CEO pay is not optimized for shareholders, nor does it imply that CEO pay needs reform. We show that in many settings where managerial power exists, observed contracts anticipate and try to minimize the costs of this power, and therefore may in fact be written optimally. As a result, the optimal contracting and managerial power perspectives are complementary, and not competing, explanations. We next examine Bebchuk and Fried's claim that U.S. compensation is inefficient \"pay without performance.\" Their analysis focuses on whether CEO annual pay varies with firm performance. While the book conducts an extensive analysis of the incentives provided by annual grants of stock options and equity it largely ignores the main source of CEO incentives: Large holdings of stock and options. These large equity holdings provide powerful performance incentives and ensure that the wealth of most CEOs varies strongly with their firm's stock price. The books' claim that CEO compensation is \"pay without performance\" does not appear correct once one considers this main source of CEO incentives. U.S. executives have very large pay-performance incentives, and their overall pay levels do not seem inappropriate. We conclude by examining some of Bebchuk and Fried's policy recommendations. Bebchuk and Fried have missed some important aspects of executive pay and incentives. They have not shown that there are systematic failures with U.S. CEO compensation, and therefore have not shown that reform is needed.","PeriodicalId":355618,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Organizations & Markets: Personnel Management (Topic)","volume":"58 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2005-04-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"105","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"ERN: Other Organizations & Markets: Personnel Management (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.648648","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 105

Abstract

In this paper, we review Pay Without Performance by Professors Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried. The book develops and summarizes the leading critiques of current executive compensation practices in the U.S., and offers a negative, if mainstream, assessment of the state of U.S. executive compensation: U.S. executive compensation practices are failing, and systemic reform is needed. This review summarizes the book in some detail and offers some counter-arguments. The book's thesis is that executive compensation practices are bad for shareholders (not "optimal") because they are the product of "managerial power." Managerial power arises because boards of directors at public companies are not independent of executives. Weak compensation committees thus do little to protect the firm in its pay negotiations with the CEO, leading to levels of executive pay that are both inappropriately high and have inappropriately low levels of incentives. The authors offer a four part analysis of CEO pay. First, they describe and critique optimal contracting theory, which posits that executive compensation arrangements are designed to benefit shareholders. Second, they explain managerial power theory, in part through an in-depth analysis of current executive compensation practices. They assert the managerial power theory provides a superior explanation of current practices to the optimal contracting perspective. They also draw the strong implication that if managerial power exists, it means that something is wrong with the contracting process. Third, they claim that CEO compensation does not vary sufficiently with firm performance. They conclude with policy recommendations for changing compensation plans and improving corporate governance, for example by requiring that directors be more independent. We agree that it is useful to consider the effect of managerial power on compensation, but we disagree with their interpretation of the consequences of this power. It is true that contract structures reflect CEO power, and that CEOs with more power get more pay, but this does not necessarily lead to the conclusion that CEO pay is not optimized for shareholders, nor does it imply that CEO pay needs reform. We show that in many settings where managerial power exists, observed contracts anticipate and try to minimize the costs of this power, and therefore may in fact be written optimally. As a result, the optimal contracting and managerial power perspectives are complementary, and not competing, explanations. We next examine Bebchuk and Fried's claim that U.S. compensation is inefficient "pay without performance." Their analysis focuses on whether CEO annual pay varies with firm performance. While the book conducts an extensive analysis of the incentives provided by annual grants of stock options and equity it largely ignores the main source of CEO incentives: Large holdings of stock and options. These large equity holdings provide powerful performance incentives and ensure that the wealth of most CEOs varies strongly with their firm's stock price. The books' claim that CEO compensation is "pay without performance" does not appear correct once one considers this main source of CEO incentives. U.S. executives have very large pay-performance incentives, and their overall pay levels do not seem inappropriate. We conclude by examining some of Bebchuk and Fried's policy recommendations. Bebchuk and Fried have missed some important aspects of executive pay and incentives. They have not shown that there are systematic failures with U.S. CEO compensation, and therefore have not shown that reform is needed.
美国CEO薪酬是否缺乏效率?
本文回顾了Lucian Bebchuk和Jesse Fried教授的“薪酬与绩效无关”理论。这本书发展并总结了对美国当前高管薪酬做法的主要批评,并对美国高管薪酬状况提出了一个负面的(如果是主流的话)评估:美国高管薪酬做法正在失败,需要进行系统性改革。这篇评论对这本书进行了一些详细的总结,并提出了一些反对意见。这本书的论点是,高管薪酬做法对股东不利(并非“最优”),因为它们是“管理权力”的产物。管理权力之所以产生,是因为上市公司的董事会并非独立于高管。因此,在与首席执行官的薪酬谈判中,软弱的薪酬委员会几乎无法保护公司,导致高管的薪酬水平既高得不合适,又低得不合适。作者对CEO薪酬进行了四部分分析。首先,他们描述并批判了最优契约理论,该理论假定高管薪酬安排是为了股东利益而设计的。其次,他们通过对当前高管薪酬实践的深入分析,部分解释了管理权力理论。他们认为管理权力理论比最优契约理论更能解释当前的实践。它们还强烈暗示,如果管理权力存在,就意味着承包过程出了问题。第三,他们声称CEO薪酬与公司业绩的差异并不大。他们最后提出了改变薪酬计划和改善公司治理的政策建议,例如要求董事更加独立。我们同意考虑管理权力对薪酬的影响是有用的,但我们不同意他们对这种权力后果的解释。诚然,合同结构反映了CEO的权力,权力越大的CEO薪酬越高,但这并不一定意味着CEO薪酬没有为股东优化,也不意味着CEO薪酬需要改革。我们表明,在许多管理权力存在的环境中,遵守的合同预期并试图最小化这种权力的成本,因此实际上可能是最优的。因此,最优契约和管理权力的观点是互补的,而不是相互竞争的。接下来,我们将研究Bebchuk和Fried关于美国薪酬效率低下的说法,即“无绩效的薪酬”。他们的分析重点是CEO的年薪是否随公司业绩而变化。虽然这本书对每年授予股票期权和股权所提供的激励进行了广泛的分析,但它在很大程度上忽略了首席执行官激励的主要来源:大量持有股票和期权。这些大量的股权提供了强大的绩效激励,并确保大多数首席执行官的财富与他们公司的股票价格密切相关。一旦考虑到CEO激励的主要来源,这些书中关于CEO薪酬是“无绩效的薪酬”的说法似乎就不正确了。美国高管有非常大的薪酬绩效激励,他们的总体薪酬水平似乎并不不合适。最后,我们考察了Bebchuk和Fried的一些政策建议。Bebchuk和Fried忽略了高管薪酬和激励的一些重要方面。他们没有显示出美国CEO薪酬存在系统性缺陷,因此也没有显示出改革的必要性。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信