Marketable Product: What Did Kuntz Say? What Did Merrill Say?

O. L. Anderson
{"title":"Marketable Product: What Did Kuntz Say? What Did Merrill Say?","authors":"O. L. Anderson","doi":"10.15781/T2Q10X","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"I have written extensively about the marketable-product approach to royalty valuation, first articulated by the late Professor Maurice Merrill in his volume dealing with implied covenants and subsequently by the late Professor Eugene Kuntz in his seminal legal treatise on oil and gas law. Two companion articles contained a thorough - some might say exhausting - discussion of royalty valuation commentary and case law, including a discussion of the views of Kuntz and Merrill. My limited purpose today is to focus on the views of Kuntz and Merrill without discussing the full myriad of case law on this divisive topic.In my opinion, the Kuntz marketable-product approach represents the appropriate default rule for royalty valuation. Unfortunately, Kuntz’s logical and sensible view has been rejected by lawyers for royalty owners and lawyers for lessees because neither group is happy with what would be the resulting outcome. Lawyers for lessees believe that Kuntz’s and Merrill’s views go too far in protecting the interests of royalty owners. Lawyers for royalty owners believe that Kuntz’s and Merrill’s views do not go far enough in protecting the interests of royalty owners. Thus, when making royalty valuation arguments, both groups of lawyers take an “all or nothing” approach. As a result, and even more unfortunately, some courts have adopted this “all or nothing” approach to royalty valuation - some ruling in favor of royalty owners and some ruling in favor of lessees. At one extreme are the Alberta courts, where royalty valuation occurs at the mouth of the well. When calculating royalty in Alberta, lessees are allowed to deduct the costs of separating the oil and gas stream from associated saltwater as well as the costs associated with saltwater disposal. Even Texas has not gone this far - at least not yet, holding, under a common bifurcated royalty clause providing from proceeds of sale at the well or market value at the well for sales off the premises, that royalty must be valued on the leased premises, not strictly at the mouth of the well. The Texas court is so attached to its view that it even held that language expressly disallowing post-lease deductions was “surplusage” where the basic royalty clause called for royalty valuation “at the well.”The fact that some courts, including Texas, have rejected the Kuntz and Merrill approaches outright is puzzling since none of Kuntz’s contemporary scholars, including A. W. Walker, Jr., Howard Williams, or Charles Meyers, ever expressly disagreed with them about royalty-valuation. Kuntz’s immediate successor at the University of Oklahoma, Richard Hemingway, supported the marketable-product approach as the better one.At the other extreme is West Virginia, where the court essentially held that royalty is payable at the ultimate point of an actual arm’s-length sale, no matter how far downstream of the well that such a sale might occur - apparently even if the actual sale occurs at a location beyond an established market that is closer to the well. Not even Colorado has gone this far, but Colorado does require the lessee to pay royalty on gas that is in both a first marketable condition and at a first-market location. Clearly, the courts of Colorado and West Virginia have gone well beyond both Kuntz and Merrill. Indeed, in the leading West Virginia case, the court cited neither Kuntz nor Merrill.Oklahoma and Kansas are somewhere between the Texas and West Virginia extremes, so far closer to the Merrill and Kuntz approach. Because Professors Kuntz and Merrill are revered in Oklahoma and because existing royalty-valuation case law in both Kansas and Oklahoma are similar, one or both courts may end up where Kuntz or Merrill have argued. Kansas case law and perhaps Oklahoma case law are closest to the Kuntz and Merrill views. Neither the Kansas nor Oklahoma Supreme Court has expressly rejected what either Kuntz or Merrill have said about royalty valuation. Neither court has intentionally adopted either a rule of law or a rule of construction radically different from what Kuntz and Merrill have said in their respective treatises about royalty valuation.A careful reading of Kuntz and Merrill illustrates that neither scholar was out to make a radical change in royalty-valuation as practiced in the industry at the time of their writings - Merrill in the 1930s and Kuntz in the 1950s. Cases cited favorably by both scholars supported their measured approaches as explained in their respective treatises. Nevertheless, Professor Kuntz did take a somewhat different approach to royalty valuation than Merrill - a difference that is apparent when one compares what Kuntz said and where he said it in his treatise on oil and gas law with what Merrill says in his treatise on implied covenants. Notwithstanding the fact that Professors Kuntz and Merrill agree on the destination - that the marketable-product approach is the appropriate default rule - they reach their destination by different paths. Kuntz’s path follows the tracks of typical royalty clauses found in oil and gas leases. Merrill’s path does not track royalty clauses. Merrill chooses his own path - mapped out by his view of the implied covenant to market. Some courts have failed to recognize these different paths. For example, although the Colorado Supreme Court has cited Kuntz, the court’s own analysis is much closer to Merrill’s view.","PeriodicalId":388507,"journal":{"name":"Energy Law & Policy eJournal","volume":"23 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2015-12-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Energy Law & Policy eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.15781/T2Q10X","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

I have written extensively about the marketable-product approach to royalty valuation, first articulated by the late Professor Maurice Merrill in his volume dealing with implied covenants and subsequently by the late Professor Eugene Kuntz in his seminal legal treatise on oil and gas law. Two companion articles contained a thorough - some might say exhausting - discussion of royalty valuation commentary and case law, including a discussion of the views of Kuntz and Merrill. My limited purpose today is to focus on the views of Kuntz and Merrill without discussing the full myriad of case law on this divisive topic.In my opinion, the Kuntz marketable-product approach represents the appropriate default rule for royalty valuation. Unfortunately, Kuntz’s logical and sensible view has been rejected by lawyers for royalty owners and lawyers for lessees because neither group is happy with what would be the resulting outcome. Lawyers for lessees believe that Kuntz’s and Merrill’s views go too far in protecting the interests of royalty owners. Lawyers for royalty owners believe that Kuntz’s and Merrill’s views do not go far enough in protecting the interests of royalty owners. Thus, when making royalty valuation arguments, both groups of lawyers take an “all or nothing” approach. As a result, and even more unfortunately, some courts have adopted this “all or nothing” approach to royalty valuation - some ruling in favor of royalty owners and some ruling in favor of lessees. At one extreme are the Alberta courts, where royalty valuation occurs at the mouth of the well. When calculating royalty in Alberta, lessees are allowed to deduct the costs of separating the oil and gas stream from associated saltwater as well as the costs associated with saltwater disposal. Even Texas has not gone this far - at least not yet, holding, under a common bifurcated royalty clause providing from proceeds of sale at the well or market value at the well for sales off the premises, that royalty must be valued on the leased premises, not strictly at the mouth of the well. The Texas court is so attached to its view that it even held that language expressly disallowing post-lease deductions was “surplusage” where the basic royalty clause called for royalty valuation “at the well.”The fact that some courts, including Texas, have rejected the Kuntz and Merrill approaches outright is puzzling since none of Kuntz’s contemporary scholars, including A. W. Walker, Jr., Howard Williams, or Charles Meyers, ever expressly disagreed with them about royalty-valuation. Kuntz’s immediate successor at the University of Oklahoma, Richard Hemingway, supported the marketable-product approach as the better one.At the other extreme is West Virginia, where the court essentially held that royalty is payable at the ultimate point of an actual arm’s-length sale, no matter how far downstream of the well that such a sale might occur - apparently even if the actual sale occurs at a location beyond an established market that is closer to the well. Not even Colorado has gone this far, but Colorado does require the lessee to pay royalty on gas that is in both a first marketable condition and at a first-market location. Clearly, the courts of Colorado and West Virginia have gone well beyond both Kuntz and Merrill. Indeed, in the leading West Virginia case, the court cited neither Kuntz nor Merrill.Oklahoma and Kansas are somewhere between the Texas and West Virginia extremes, so far closer to the Merrill and Kuntz approach. Because Professors Kuntz and Merrill are revered in Oklahoma and because existing royalty-valuation case law in both Kansas and Oklahoma are similar, one or both courts may end up where Kuntz or Merrill have argued. Kansas case law and perhaps Oklahoma case law are closest to the Kuntz and Merrill views. Neither the Kansas nor Oklahoma Supreme Court has expressly rejected what either Kuntz or Merrill have said about royalty valuation. Neither court has intentionally adopted either a rule of law or a rule of construction radically different from what Kuntz and Merrill have said in their respective treatises about royalty valuation.A careful reading of Kuntz and Merrill illustrates that neither scholar was out to make a radical change in royalty-valuation as practiced in the industry at the time of their writings - Merrill in the 1930s and Kuntz in the 1950s. Cases cited favorably by both scholars supported their measured approaches as explained in their respective treatises. Nevertheless, Professor Kuntz did take a somewhat different approach to royalty valuation than Merrill - a difference that is apparent when one compares what Kuntz said and where he said it in his treatise on oil and gas law with what Merrill says in his treatise on implied covenants. Notwithstanding the fact that Professors Kuntz and Merrill agree on the destination - that the marketable-product approach is the appropriate default rule - they reach their destination by different paths. Kuntz’s path follows the tracks of typical royalty clauses found in oil and gas leases. Merrill’s path does not track royalty clauses. Merrill chooses his own path - mapped out by his view of the implied covenant to market. Some courts have failed to recognize these different paths. For example, although the Colorado Supreme Court has cited Kuntz, the court’s own analysis is much closer to Merrill’s view.
畅销产品:昆茨说了什么?美林说了什么?
我写了大量关于可销售产品的特许权使用费评估方法的文章,首先由已故的Maurice Merrill教授在他的关于隐含契约的著作中阐述,随后由已故的Eugene Kuntz教授在他关于石油和天然气法的开创性法律论文中阐述。另外两篇文章对版税估价评论和判例法进行了彻底的——有人可能会说令人筋疲力尽的——讨论,其中包括对昆茨和梅里尔观点的讨论。我今天有限的目的是集中讨论昆茨和梅里尔的观点,而不是讨论关于这个有争议的话题的无数判例法。在我看来,Kuntz的可销售产品方法代表了版税估值的适当默认规则。不幸的是,昆茨合乎逻辑且明智的观点遭到了代表版税所有者和承租人的律师的反对,因为双方都对最终的结果不满意。承租人的律师认为,昆茨和梅里尔的观点在保护版税所有者的利益方面走得太远了。版税所有者的律师认为,昆茨和梅里尔的观点在保护版税所有者的利益方面做得不够。因此,在进行特许权使用费评估辩论时,两组律师都采取了“全有或全无”的方法。结果,甚至更不幸的是,一些法院采用了这种“全有或全无”的方法来评估特许权使用费——一些裁决有利于特许权使用费所有者,而另一些裁决有利于承租人。一个极端是阿尔伯塔法院,在那里,特许权使用费的估价发生在井口。在计算艾伯塔省的特许权使用费时,承租人可以扣除将油气流与相关盐水分离的成本,以及与盐水处理相关的成本。即使是德克萨斯州也没有走到这一步——至少目前还没有,根据一项共同的分拆特许权使用费条款,该条款规定,从油井的销售收益或油井的市场价值中出售,特许权使用费必须在租赁场所进行评估,而不是严格地在井口进行评估。德克萨斯州法院如此执着于自己的观点,以至于它甚至认为,在基本特许权使用费条款要求“在油井”进行特许权使用费评估的情况下,明确禁止租赁后扣除的语言是“剩余使用”。包括德克萨斯州在内的一些法院直接拒绝昆茨和梅里尔的方法,这一事实令人费解,因为与昆茨同时代的学者,包括小沃克(A. W. Walker, Jr.)、霍华德·威廉姆斯(Howard Williams)或查尔斯·迈耶斯(Charles Meyers),都没有明确反对过他们对版税估值的看法。昆茨在俄克拉何马大学的直接继任者理查德·海明威(Richard Hemingway)支持可销售产品的方法,认为这种方法更好。另一个极端是西弗吉尼亚州,在那里,法院基本上认为,在实际的公平销售的最终点支付特许权使用费,无论这种销售可能发生在油井下游多远的地方——显然,即使实际销售发生在离油井更近的既定市场之外的地方。即使是科罗拉多州也没有走到这一步,但科罗拉多州确实要求承租人为处于第一市场条件和第一市场位置的天然气支付特许权使用费。显然,科罗拉多州和西弗吉尼亚州的法院已经远远超出了昆茨和梅里尔的范围。事实上,在西弗吉尼亚州的主要案件中,法院既没有引用昆茨的证词,也没有引用美林的证词。俄克拉何马州和堪萨斯州处于德克萨斯州和西弗吉尼亚州的极端之间,因此更接近梅里尔和昆茨的方法。因为昆茨教授和梅里尔教授在俄克拉何马州很受尊敬,而且堪萨斯州和俄克拉何马州现有的版税估价判例法相似,一个或两个法院可能会以昆茨或梅里尔所主张的方式告终。堪萨斯州的判例法和俄克拉何马州的判例法最接近昆茨和梅里尔的观点。堪萨斯州和俄克拉何马州的最高法院都没有明确拒绝昆茨和梅里尔关于特许权使用费估值的说法。两家法院都没有刻意采用与Kuntz和Merrill在他们各自关于特许权使用费评估的论文中所述截然不同的法律规则或构建规则。仔细阅读昆茨和梅里尔的著作就会发现,两位学者都没有打算彻底改变版税估价的做法,就像他们写作的时候——梅里尔在20世纪30年代,昆茨在50年代。两位学者引用的有利案例支持他们在各自的论文中解释的测量方法。尽管如此,Kuntz教授确实采取了一种与Merrill不同的方法来评估特许权使用费——当人们将Kuntz在他关于石油和天然气法的专著中所说的话和Merrill在他关于默示契约的专著中所说的话进行比较时,这种差异就很明显了。 尽管昆茨教授和梅里尔教授在目标上达成了一致——即产品市场化方法是合适的默认规则——但他们通过不同的途径达到了目标。昆茨的做法遵循了石油和天然气租赁中典型的特许权使用费条款。美林的做法不涉及特许权使用费条款。美林选择了自己的道路——这是他对市场默示契约的看法勾勒出来的。一些法院未能认识到这些不同的途径。例如,尽管科罗拉多州最高法院引用了昆茨的观点,但法院自己的分析更接近梅里尔的观点。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信