Unemployment Insurance and Duration of Unemployment: Evidence from Slovenia's Transition

Milan Vodopivec
{"title":"Unemployment Insurance and Duration of Unemployment: Evidence from Slovenia's Transition","authors":"Milan Vodopivec","doi":"10.1596/1813-9450-1552","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Between 1990 and 1992 in Slovenia, recipients of unemployment insurance (UI) benefits tended to remain (formally) unemployed until their benefits expired, before taking a job. Institutional set-up suggests, and labor surveys show, that many of the recipients were actually working while collecting UI benefits. In the spirit, if not in the letter of the law, the UI system was abused. The author shows that the escape rate of the recipients of unemployment compensation to employment increased dramatically just before the potential exhaustion of unemployment benefits - and decreased equally dramatically after benefits were exhausted. When grouped by the potential duration of benefits, unemployment length varies significantly. The unemployed with longer potential benefits stay unemployed longer. Because these groups differ in their characteristics (for example, in age), this does not prove the\"waiting behavior\"of the recipients. However, exits to employment dramatically increase just before exhaustion - and that does prove waiting behavior. The pattern of an increased escape rate just before benefits are exhausted and its dramatic fall thereafter is more rigorously demonstrated using hazard model estimation. Possibilities for informal employment are abundant in Slovenia, and the environment of transition economies generally seems conducive to misuse of the UI system. Legislative loopholes and failure to enforce the labor code allowed the unemployed to work and to collect benefits. The monitoring of job searches was also lax. The author's calculations suggest that reducing the duration of benefits would reduce the incidence of unemployment, its duration, the amount spent on UI benefits, and the inefficiencies generated by raising taxes to finance unemployment insurance. At the same time, reducing the duration of benefits would not impair job matches or crowd out jobs for nonrecipients. True, despite increased efficiency generally, the workers with the least job mobility might suffer hardships for the least mobile group and greater efficiency generally would have to be resolved in the political sphere. Redesigning the system for better targeting would be less controversial. One way to reduce UI spending without seriously curtailing incentives to work would be to reduce the benefits in proportion to earnings from irregular work. Another possibility is stricter monitoring of the job searches of the unemployed. To reduce spending and make\"double dipping\"less attractive, old-age insurance could be removed from the package of benefits the UI system offers. Also, counselors who help the unemployed find jobs (and who may thus develop a close relationship with them) should perhaps not be expected to be able to make impartial decisions about disqualifications for benefits; someone else should do that. In addition to better targeting, a\"benefit transfer program\"- a voluntary program that converts UI benefits Also, counselors who help the unemployed find jobs (through vouchers) into hiring subsidies - seems particularly attractive for Slovenia and other transition economies. In a way, such a program would legalize the\"double-dipping\"that has been taking place in Slovenia and possibly elsewhere. It would legalize practices that have undermined the system's credibility. But it might improve fiscal savings while sustaining the incentive to find jobs.","PeriodicalId":357008,"journal":{"name":"Employment Law eJournal","volume":"23 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1995-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"29","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Employment Law eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-1552","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 29

Abstract

Between 1990 and 1992 in Slovenia, recipients of unemployment insurance (UI) benefits tended to remain (formally) unemployed until their benefits expired, before taking a job. Institutional set-up suggests, and labor surveys show, that many of the recipients were actually working while collecting UI benefits. In the spirit, if not in the letter of the law, the UI system was abused. The author shows that the escape rate of the recipients of unemployment compensation to employment increased dramatically just before the potential exhaustion of unemployment benefits - and decreased equally dramatically after benefits were exhausted. When grouped by the potential duration of benefits, unemployment length varies significantly. The unemployed with longer potential benefits stay unemployed longer. Because these groups differ in their characteristics (for example, in age), this does not prove the"waiting behavior"of the recipients. However, exits to employment dramatically increase just before exhaustion - and that does prove waiting behavior. The pattern of an increased escape rate just before benefits are exhausted and its dramatic fall thereafter is more rigorously demonstrated using hazard model estimation. Possibilities for informal employment are abundant in Slovenia, and the environment of transition economies generally seems conducive to misuse of the UI system. Legislative loopholes and failure to enforce the labor code allowed the unemployed to work and to collect benefits. The monitoring of job searches was also lax. The author's calculations suggest that reducing the duration of benefits would reduce the incidence of unemployment, its duration, the amount spent on UI benefits, and the inefficiencies generated by raising taxes to finance unemployment insurance. At the same time, reducing the duration of benefits would not impair job matches or crowd out jobs for nonrecipients. True, despite increased efficiency generally, the workers with the least job mobility might suffer hardships for the least mobile group and greater efficiency generally would have to be resolved in the political sphere. Redesigning the system for better targeting would be less controversial. One way to reduce UI spending without seriously curtailing incentives to work would be to reduce the benefits in proportion to earnings from irregular work. Another possibility is stricter monitoring of the job searches of the unemployed. To reduce spending and make"double dipping"less attractive, old-age insurance could be removed from the package of benefits the UI system offers. Also, counselors who help the unemployed find jobs (and who may thus develop a close relationship with them) should perhaps not be expected to be able to make impartial decisions about disqualifications for benefits; someone else should do that. In addition to better targeting, a"benefit transfer program"- a voluntary program that converts UI benefits Also, counselors who help the unemployed find jobs (through vouchers) into hiring subsidies - seems particularly attractive for Slovenia and other transition economies. In a way, such a program would legalize the"double-dipping"that has been taking place in Slovenia and possibly elsewhere. It would legalize practices that have undermined the system's credibility. But it might improve fiscal savings while sustaining the incentive to find jobs.
失业保险与失业持续时间:来自斯洛文尼亚转型的证据
1990年至1992年间,在斯洛文尼亚,领取失业保险(UI)的人往往(正式地)处于失业状态,直到他们的福利到期,然后才开始工作。制度设置表明,劳工调查显示,许多领取失业救济金的人实际上是在工作。在精神上,如果不是在法律的文字上,UI系统被滥用了。作者表明,在失业救济可能用尽之前,失业救济受助者逃避就业的比率急剧上升,而在失业救济用尽之后,逃避就业的比率同样急剧下降。当按潜在的福利持续时间分组时,失业时间长短变化很大。拥有更长的潜在福利的失业者失业的时间更长。由于这些群体的特征(例如年龄)不同,这并不能证明接受者的“等待行为”。然而,在精疲力竭之前退出就业的人数急剧增加——这确实证明了等待行为。利用危险模型估算,更严格地证明了在福利耗尽之前逃逸率增加而随后急剧下降的模式。斯洛文尼亚非正规就业的可能性很大,而转型期经济的环境一般看来有利于滥用失业保险制度。立法漏洞和劳动法执行不力使失业者得以工作和领取福利。对求职的监控也很松懈。作者的计算表明,减少失业救济的持续时间将减少失业的发生率、失业救济的持续时间、用于失业救济金的金额,以及通过提高税收为失业保险提供资金而产生的低效率。与此同时,减少福利的持续时间不会影响工作匹配或挤占非受助人的工作。的确,尽管总体上提高了效率,但工作流动性最低的工人可能会为流动性最低的群体遭受苦难,而总体上提高效率必须在政治领域得到解决。重新设计系统以更好地瞄准目标将会减少争议。在不严重削弱工作激励的情况下,减少失业保险支出的一种方法是,按不定期工作的收入比例减少福利。另一种可能是对失业者的求职进行更严格的监控。为了减少支出,降低“双底浸入”的吸引力,养老保险可以从失业保险制度提供的一揽子福利中移除。此外,帮助失业者找工作的咨询师(他们可能因此与失业者建立了密切的关系)也许不应该被期望能够对取消领取福利的资格做出公正的决定;应该由别人来做。除了更好地定位外,“福利转移计划”——一个将失业保险福利和帮助失业者找工作的顾问(通过代金券)转化为雇佣补贴的自愿计划——似乎对斯洛文尼亚和其他转型经济体特别有吸引力。在某种程度上,这样的计划将使已经在斯洛文尼亚和其他地方发生的“双底捞”合法化。它将使破坏金融体系可信度的行为合法化。但它可能会改善财政储蓄,同时保持找工作的动力。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信