History of Economic Thought - What For? Empirical Observations From German Universities

Juergen G. Backhaus
{"title":"History of Economic Thought - What For? Empirical Observations From German Universities","authors":"Juergen G. Backhaus","doi":"10.1017/S1042771600003914","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"With this note I am providing a brief English summary and some extensions of an investigation (Backhaus 1983) that tried to answer two questions: a) Has the instruction in the history of economic thought vanished from the curricula of German universities, especially after the extensive reforms of the late sixties and early seventies? b) Can we identify purposes for offering courses in the history of economic thought? The survey spans the entire post WW II period until March 1980. \"German\" refers to the primary language of instruction. Hence, Austrian and several Swiss universities were included. The East German universities had to be excluded, for several reasons. One of them is that neither their organization nor purposes are readily comparable with Western institutions of higher learning. The study was prompted by often voiced concerns that the history of economic thought had virtually disappeared from the economics curriculum (e.g Schefold 1981; 53). We also sought to update an earlier study undertaken before the university reforms (Schultz 1960). But the scope of the survey went a bit beyond such a statistical exercise as we tried to find some hints about the uses and purposes of the history of economic thought as revealed in the practice of teaching the subject matter. In principle, there are at least four ways to answer the question \"History of Economic Thought What For?\" One may firstly speculate about possible purposes and applications; employ methods of literary interpretation in surveying earlier attempts along similar lines; in order to amicably urge others to follow the guidelines of a program thus derived. This is the approach characteristic of the largest part of the substantial body of literature discussing the purposes of doctrinal history. Secondly, we can consult the published record and determine what difference the use of historical analysis makes in published research. This will yield but a distorted picture. In many European universities, the emphasis on publishing research is much slighter than in their North America counterparts. Scholars like the late Piero Sraffa often command respect primarily for their contributions to the oral tradition. While the oral tradition has always remained important, publishing research may often be almost accidental in European academe. Thirdly, one could analyze survey data. While the problems associated with this method are generally recognized, this often proves to be the only feasible method. In trying to retain some comparabability with the 1960 survey, while still overcoming many of its shortcomings, we resorted to a fourth approach which combines elements of all three methods and adds a twist. Forthly, an analysis of the course titles will reveal a great deal about their contents. While in America, course titles tend to be standardized and are unlikely to vary with the instructor who happens to teach the course, this is not so in the German university. The curriculum guidelines tend to be more general, and each chair is generally responsible for the development of an area of research and instruction in a particular subdiscipline of economics. Hence, the course titles (and contents) are the work of the professor who offers the course and who tries to announce precisely what the course is going to be about.","PeriodicalId":123974,"journal":{"name":"History of Economics Society Bulletin","volume":"46 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1986-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"2","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"History of Economics Society Bulletin","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1042771600003914","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2

Abstract

With this note I am providing a brief English summary and some extensions of an investigation (Backhaus 1983) that tried to answer two questions: a) Has the instruction in the history of economic thought vanished from the curricula of German universities, especially after the extensive reforms of the late sixties and early seventies? b) Can we identify purposes for offering courses in the history of economic thought? The survey spans the entire post WW II period until March 1980. "German" refers to the primary language of instruction. Hence, Austrian and several Swiss universities were included. The East German universities had to be excluded, for several reasons. One of them is that neither their organization nor purposes are readily comparable with Western institutions of higher learning. The study was prompted by often voiced concerns that the history of economic thought had virtually disappeared from the economics curriculum (e.g Schefold 1981; 53). We also sought to update an earlier study undertaken before the university reforms (Schultz 1960). But the scope of the survey went a bit beyond such a statistical exercise as we tried to find some hints about the uses and purposes of the history of economic thought as revealed in the practice of teaching the subject matter. In principle, there are at least four ways to answer the question "History of Economic Thought What For?" One may firstly speculate about possible purposes and applications; employ methods of literary interpretation in surveying earlier attempts along similar lines; in order to amicably urge others to follow the guidelines of a program thus derived. This is the approach characteristic of the largest part of the substantial body of literature discussing the purposes of doctrinal history. Secondly, we can consult the published record and determine what difference the use of historical analysis makes in published research. This will yield but a distorted picture. In many European universities, the emphasis on publishing research is much slighter than in their North America counterparts. Scholars like the late Piero Sraffa often command respect primarily for their contributions to the oral tradition. While the oral tradition has always remained important, publishing research may often be almost accidental in European academe. Thirdly, one could analyze survey data. While the problems associated with this method are generally recognized, this often proves to be the only feasible method. In trying to retain some comparabability with the 1960 survey, while still overcoming many of its shortcomings, we resorted to a fourth approach which combines elements of all three methods and adds a twist. Forthly, an analysis of the course titles will reveal a great deal about their contents. While in America, course titles tend to be standardized and are unlikely to vary with the instructor who happens to teach the course, this is not so in the German university. The curriculum guidelines tend to be more general, and each chair is generally responsible for the development of an area of research and instruction in a particular subdiscipline of economics. Hence, the course titles (and contents) are the work of the professor who offers the course and who tries to announce precisely what the course is going to be about.
经济思想史——为什么?来自德国大学的实证观察
在这篇文章中,我提供了一份简短的英文摘要,并对一项调查(Backhaus 1983)进行了一些延伸,该调查试图回答两个问题:a)经济思想史的教学是否从德国大学的课程中消失了,尤其是在60年代末和70年代初的广泛改革之后?b)我们能确定开设经济思想史课程的目的吗?该调查涵盖了二战后至1980年3月的整个时期。“德语”是指教学的主要语言。因此,奥地利和瑞士的几所大学也被列入其中。由于几个原因,东德的大学必须被排除在外。其中之一是,它们的组织和目的都无法与西方的高等教育机构相提并论。人们经常担心经济思想史实际上已经从经济学课程中消失,这促使了这项研究的开展(例如Schefold 1981;53)。我们还试图更新大学改革之前进行的一项早期研究(Schultz 1960)。但调查的范围超出了这样的统计练习,因为我们试图找到一些关于经济思想史的用途和目的的暗示,正如在教学实践中所揭示的那样。原则上,至少有四种方法可以回答“经济思想史为什么?”人们可以首先推测可能的目的和应用;采用文学解释的方法来考察类似的早期尝试;为了友好地敦促他人遵循由此衍生的程序的指导方针。这是讨论教义史目的的大量文献中最具特色的方法。其次,我们可以参考已发表的记录,确定使用历史分析在已发表的研究中有什么不同。这只会产生一幅扭曲的画面。与北美大学相比,许多欧洲大学对发表研究成果的重视程度要低得多。像已故的皮耶罗·斯拉法这样的学者常常因为他们对口头传统的贡献而受到尊敬。虽然口述传统一直很重要,但在欧洲学术界,出版研究往往几乎是偶然的。第三,可以分析调查数据。虽然人们普遍认识到与这种方法有关的问题,但这往往被证明是唯一可行的方法。为了保持与1960年调查的可比性,同时克服它的许多缺点,我们采用了第四种方法,它结合了所有三种方法的要素并增加了一个转折。第四,通过对课程名称的分析,可以了解课程名称的内容。在美国,课程名称往往是标准化的,不太可能随着教授这门课程的老师而变化,但在德国大学却不是这样。课程指导方针往往更为笼统,每位教授通常负责经济学某一特定分支学科的研究和教学领域的发展。因此,课程名称(和内容)是教授的工作,教授开了这门课,并试图准确地宣布这门课要讲什么。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信