Tax and subsidy elements in public enterprise prices

V. Ramanadham
{"title":"Tax and subsidy elements in public enterprise prices","authors":"V. Ramanadham","doi":"10.4324/9780429200083-10","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"A public enterprise (monopoly) usually differs from a private one in four ways. These are: (1) fear of entry is less than is felt by a private monopoly; (2) public control is often ineffective; (3) there is little protest against high prices because of the notion that the profit goes to the public exchequer; and (4) there may be a covert governmental design to acquiesce in high prices as a source of revenue in lieu of taxation. These conditions permit the introduction of tax or subsidy characteristics into pricing. We shall refer to the excess of price over related cost as a tax element (and to a short-fall as subsidy). This tax (or subsidy) may be arbitrary and without public sanction. The price may exceed the limits of usual managerial authority to charge for costs (including costs of capital, even with allowance for growth). Moreover, the managers of a public enterprise are not chosen for their expertise in effecting shifts of purchasing power among consumers a prerogative of the taxing authority. Tax or subsidy elements exist (1) when an enterprise has (a) a single price exceeding the average cost, (b) a price structure involving unequal excesses of price over cost in different markets, products, uses, regions or consumer groups, or (c) a uniform price when costs of supply are dissimilar; or (2) when two or more enterprises supply the same or different products at varying excesses of price over related cost implying the choice of some consumers for more taxation than others. The price-cost differentials employed here are not those under joint supply, whose justification is that at no lower price would the supply of any one product by itself be possible. There are several ways in which the tax elements manifest themselves. First, the enterprise may transfer its profits to the government. This is provided for by many corporation acts and by the company form of organization in India. Second, and less obvious, the extracost elements may be retained in the enterprise itself for the benefit of consumers or regions other than those that contributed them. (By hypothesis, these are over and above the normal rates of self-financing.) Finally, although there may be no overall profit, there may be subtle cross-subsidizations in such a way that the over payments by some consumers or regions cancel out the under payments by others. The larger the enterprise, the more probable such a pricing system, as, for example, on the Indian railways. Alternatively, profits may be used for employee welfare expenditures far in excess of comparable expenditures by other enterprises in the economy. Involving payments by certain (consumer) groups of persons for the benefit of others, these have the characteristics of expenditures through governmental budgets. For tax elements to be present, the enterprise must have some degree of monopoly. The converse is not true, for a monopoly, through inefficiency or choice, can introduce subsidy elements into its prices. It is of value to distinguish the tax elements in public enterprise prices. It is not a matter of indifference to the consumer whether he is asked to pay a price P, in excess of the related cost, or the same amount shown as a combination of x towards related cost and y towards tax element, except in the arithmetic sense in a given short-run situation. Under the x + y system, the consumer can legitimately raise *The author is Head of the Department of Commerce, and Dean, Faculty of Commerce, Osmania University, Hyderabad, India.","PeriodicalId":243368,"journal":{"name":"The Economics of Public Enterprise","volume":"88 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1964-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"The Economics of Public Enterprise","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9780429200083-10","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

A public enterprise (monopoly) usually differs from a private one in four ways. These are: (1) fear of entry is less than is felt by a private monopoly; (2) public control is often ineffective; (3) there is little protest against high prices because of the notion that the profit goes to the public exchequer; and (4) there may be a covert governmental design to acquiesce in high prices as a source of revenue in lieu of taxation. These conditions permit the introduction of tax or subsidy characteristics into pricing. We shall refer to the excess of price over related cost as a tax element (and to a short-fall as subsidy). This tax (or subsidy) may be arbitrary and without public sanction. The price may exceed the limits of usual managerial authority to charge for costs (including costs of capital, even with allowance for growth). Moreover, the managers of a public enterprise are not chosen for their expertise in effecting shifts of purchasing power among consumers a prerogative of the taxing authority. Tax or subsidy elements exist (1) when an enterprise has (a) a single price exceeding the average cost, (b) a price structure involving unequal excesses of price over cost in different markets, products, uses, regions or consumer groups, or (c) a uniform price when costs of supply are dissimilar; or (2) when two or more enterprises supply the same or different products at varying excesses of price over related cost implying the choice of some consumers for more taxation than others. The price-cost differentials employed here are not those under joint supply, whose justification is that at no lower price would the supply of any one product by itself be possible. There are several ways in which the tax elements manifest themselves. First, the enterprise may transfer its profits to the government. This is provided for by many corporation acts and by the company form of organization in India. Second, and less obvious, the extracost elements may be retained in the enterprise itself for the benefit of consumers or regions other than those that contributed them. (By hypothesis, these are over and above the normal rates of self-financing.) Finally, although there may be no overall profit, there may be subtle cross-subsidizations in such a way that the over payments by some consumers or regions cancel out the under payments by others. The larger the enterprise, the more probable such a pricing system, as, for example, on the Indian railways. Alternatively, profits may be used for employee welfare expenditures far in excess of comparable expenditures by other enterprises in the economy. Involving payments by certain (consumer) groups of persons for the benefit of others, these have the characteristics of expenditures through governmental budgets. For tax elements to be present, the enterprise must have some degree of monopoly. The converse is not true, for a monopoly, through inefficiency or choice, can introduce subsidy elements into its prices. It is of value to distinguish the tax elements in public enterprise prices. It is not a matter of indifference to the consumer whether he is asked to pay a price P, in excess of the related cost, or the same amount shown as a combination of x towards related cost and y towards tax element, except in the arithmetic sense in a given short-run situation. Under the x + y system, the consumer can legitimately raise *The author is Head of the Department of Commerce, and Dean, Faculty of Commerce, Osmania University, Hyderabad, India.
公共企业价格中的税收和补贴因素
公共企业(垄断企业)通常在四个方面与私营企业不同。它们是:(1)对进入的恐惧程度低于私人垄断;(2)公共控制往往无效;(3)对高价格的抗议很少,因为人们认为利润会进入公共财政;(4)政府可能暗地里默许高价作为代替税收的收入来源。这些条件允许在定价中引入税收或补贴特征。我们将把价格超过相关成本的部分作为税收因素(不足部分作为补贴)。这种税收(或补贴)可能是武断的,没有公共批准。价格可能超过通常的管理权限对成本(包括资本成本,即使考虑到增长)收取的限制。此外,选择公共企业的管理人员不是因为他们在影响消费者购买力转移方面的专业知识——这是税务当局的特权。(一)单一价格超过平均成本的,(二)不同市场、不同产品、不同用途、不同地区、不同消费群体价格超过成本不平等的价格结构,或者(三)供应成本不同的统一价格的;或者(2)两个或两个以上的企业以不同的价格超额提供相同或不同的产品,这意味着一些消费者比其他消费者选择更多的税收。这里所采用的价格成本差异并不是联合供应下的价格成本差异,联合供应的理由是任何一种产品都不可能以更低的价格单独供应。税收因素有几种表现方式。首先,企业可以将利润转移给政府。在印度,许多公司法和公司组织形式都规定了这一点。其次,不太明显的是,为了消费者或地区的利益,企业本身可能会保留成本因素,而不是那些贡献成本因素的消费者或地区的利益。(根据假设,这些都超出了正常的自筹资金率。)最后,尽管可能没有整体利润,但可能存在微妙的交叉补贴,通过这种方式,一些消费者或地区的超额支付抵消了其他消费者或地区的不足支付。企业规模越大,就越有可能采用这种定价制度,例如印度铁路。或者,利润可能用于雇员福利支出,远远超过经济中其他企业的可比支出。涉及某些(消费者)群体为他人利益而支付的款项,具有通过政府预算支出的特点。要使税收要素存在,企业必须具有一定程度的垄断。反之则不成立,因为垄断可以通过低效率或选择将补贴因素引入其价格。区分上市企业价格中的税收要素具有一定的价值。对于消费者来说,无论要求他支付超过相关成本的价格P,还是要求他支付与相关成本的x和税收元素的y的组合相同的价格P,都不是无关紧要的问题,除非在给定的短期情况下从算术意义上讲。在x + y制度下,消费者可以合法地提高*作者是印度海得拉巴Osmania大学商科系主任,商科学院院长。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信