Contracting Problems and Regulation: The Case of the Fishery

Ronald N. Johnson, G. Libecap
{"title":"Contracting Problems and Regulation: The Case of the Fishery","authors":"Ronald N. Johnson, G. Libecap","doi":"10.4324/9781315193182-21","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The inefficiencies of common property fisheries are of continuing concern to economists.' The early work by Scott Gordon (1954) and Anthony Scott (1955) outlined the problem and later studies by James Crutchfield and Giulio Pontecorvo (1969) and Frederick Bell (1972) provided empirical estimates of the losses that result. Those studies were followed by the dynamic models of Colin Clark (1976), and James Quirk and Vernon Smith (1970) of optimal harvest rates and the use of corrective taxes or quotas to achieve them. But in spite of a large and growing literature and the persuasiveness of the outlined efficiency criteria, most fisheries retain common property aspects with overcapitalization and excessive labor input. Why those conditions persist and the failure of the regulatory response to them are the issues addressed in this paper. We examine a number of fisheries, but focus on the Texas shrimp industry, which is one of the nation's most valuable fisheries for a single species and which shares the common property characteristics observed elsewhere. It is considered overcapitalized and catch per unit of effort is falling.2 Examination of the fishery reveals the many margins along which rent dissipation occurs and the nature of the regulations necessary for controlling fishing effort to avoid those losses. The regulatory environment in Texas is complicated by conflict within the fishery between inshore and offshore fishermen. The latter assert that bay shrimping reduces the number of shrimp that successfully migrate to the Gulf. The inshore fishery is highlighted by another issue-the recent resettlement of some 30-45,000 Vietnamese refugees, including many fishermen, along the Texas Coast (Marine Advisory Service, Paul Starr). Their entry has been met by hostility and violence from existing shrimpers who recognize that they are in an environment characterized by the absence of property rights. Bay shrimpers have lobbied the Texas Legislature for broad limits on new entrants. Yet, ironically, the sale of additional boats by individual shrimpers to the Vietnamese has facilitated entry of the refugees into the fishery. Regulations in the Texas shrimp and other fisheries are incomplete, leaving many options for rent dissipation uncontrolled, because of high contracting costs among fishermen and political factors that mold government actions. Contracting costs are high among heterogeneous fishermen, who vary principally with regard to fishing skill.3 *Montana State University and Texas A&M University, respectively. We benefitted from comments by Terry Anderson, Raymond C. Battalio, Gardner Brown, Oscar Burt, Micha Gisser, Wade Griffin, John R. Moroney, Anthony D. Scott, Peter Temin, and participants in workshops at Texas A&M University and the University of Washington. Research assistance was provided by Scott Barnhart and Phil Mizzi. Funding was provided by Sea Grant, Texas A&M University. 'Throughout this paper we use the terms common property and open access interchangeably. Here the terms describe a situation where no property rights, group, or individual exist(s) for the resource. 2Catch per unit of effort in the inshore Texas Gulf and Federal Gulf waters is presented for 1963-77 by W. L. Griffin, C. G. Tydlacka, and W. E. Grant. They show catch per unit of effort generally falling in inshore and offshore waters. While catch per unit of effort fluctuates from year to year, it falls from approximately 360 kg shrimp per unit of effort to 220 kg from 1963 to 1977. The common property nature of the fishery is reflected in the following statistics. Since 1975 the number of vessels has grown by 23 percent (Nelson Swartz). For fish houses the record of entry is similar. Between 1970 a d 1977, the number of firms grew from 259 to 287, though during that period, many left the industry as others entered. The number of fish houses was calculated from license data supplied by the Texas Parks and Wildlife Department. The record of entry by fish houses suggests that monopsony as discussed by Colin Clark and Gordon Munro is absent in the fishery. 3There may be minor differences in labor-leisure choices and capital, but our statistical evidence and discussions with fishermen indicate that catch variations are largely due to skill. Government regulations in the Texas bays restrict capital, and our empirical evidence shows boats to be relatively homogeneous.","PeriodicalId":305766,"journal":{"name":"Fisheries Economics","volume":"232 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"100","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Fisheries Economics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9781315193182-21","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 100

Abstract

The inefficiencies of common property fisheries are of continuing concern to economists.' The early work by Scott Gordon (1954) and Anthony Scott (1955) outlined the problem and later studies by James Crutchfield and Giulio Pontecorvo (1969) and Frederick Bell (1972) provided empirical estimates of the losses that result. Those studies were followed by the dynamic models of Colin Clark (1976), and James Quirk and Vernon Smith (1970) of optimal harvest rates and the use of corrective taxes or quotas to achieve them. But in spite of a large and growing literature and the persuasiveness of the outlined efficiency criteria, most fisheries retain common property aspects with overcapitalization and excessive labor input. Why those conditions persist and the failure of the regulatory response to them are the issues addressed in this paper. We examine a number of fisheries, but focus on the Texas shrimp industry, which is one of the nation's most valuable fisheries for a single species and which shares the common property characteristics observed elsewhere. It is considered overcapitalized and catch per unit of effort is falling.2 Examination of the fishery reveals the many margins along which rent dissipation occurs and the nature of the regulations necessary for controlling fishing effort to avoid those losses. The regulatory environment in Texas is complicated by conflict within the fishery between inshore and offshore fishermen. The latter assert that bay shrimping reduces the number of shrimp that successfully migrate to the Gulf. The inshore fishery is highlighted by another issue-the recent resettlement of some 30-45,000 Vietnamese refugees, including many fishermen, along the Texas Coast (Marine Advisory Service, Paul Starr). Their entry has been met by hostility and violence from existing shrimpers who recognize that they are in an environment characterized by the absence of property rights. Bay shrimpers have lobbied the Texas Legislature for broad limits on new entrants. Yet, ironically, the sale of additional boats by individual shrimpers to the Vietnamese has facilitated entry of the refugees into the fishery. Regulations in the Texas shrimp and other fisheries are incomplete, leaving many options for rent dissipation uncontrolled, because of high contracting costs among fishermen and political factors that mold government actions. Contracting costs are high among heterogeneous fishermen, who vary principally with regard to fishing skill.3 *Montana State University and Texas A&M University, respectively. We benefitted from comments by Terry Anderson, Raymond C. Battalio, Gardner Brown, Oscar Burt, Micha Gisser, Wade Griffin, John R. Moroney, Anthony D. Scott, Peter Temin, and participants in workshops at Texas A&M University and the University of Washington. Research assistance was provided by Scott Barnhart and Phil Mizzi. Funding was provided by Sea Grant, Texas A&M University. 'Throughout this paper we use the terms common property and open access interchangeably. Here the terms describe a situation where no property rights, group, or individual exist(s) for the resource. 2Catch per unit of effort in the inshore Texas Gulf and Federal Gulf waters is presented for 1963-77 by W. L. Griffin, C. G. Tydlacka, and W. E. Grant. They show catch per unit of effort generally falling in inshore and offshore waters. While catch per unit of effort fluctuates from year to year, it falls from approximately 360 kg shrimp per unit of effort to 220 kg from 1963 to 1977. The common property nature of the fishery is reflected in the following statistics. Since 1975 the number of vessels has grown by 23 percent (Nelson Swartz). For fish houses the record of entry is similar. Between 1970 a d 1977, the number of firms grew from 259 to 287, though during that period, many left the industry as others entered. The number of fish houses was calculated from license data supplied by the Texas Parks and Wildlife Department. The record of entry by fish houses suggests that monopsony as discussed by Colin Clark and Gordon Munro is absent in the fishery. 3There may be minor differences in labor-leisure choices and capital, but our statistical evidence and discussions with fishermen indicate that catch variations are largely due to skill. Government regulations in the Texas bays restrict capital, and our empirical evidence shows boats to be relatively homogeneous.
契约问题与规制:以渔业为例
共有财产渔业的低效率一直是经济学家关注的问题。斯科特·戈登(1954年)和安东尼·斯科特(1955年)的早期工作概述了这个问题,詹姆斯·克拉奇菲尔德和朱利奥·蓬特科尔沃(1969年)以及弗雷德里克·贝尔(1972年)的后期研究提供了由此导致的损失的实证估计。在这些研究之后,科林·克拉克(1976)、詹姆斯·夸克和弗农·史密斯(1970)提出了最佳收获率的动态模型,并利用纠正性税收或配额来实现这些模型。但是,尽管有大量和不断增长的文献和概述的效率标准的说服力,大多数渔业保留了资本过剩和过度劳动投入的共同财产方面。为什么这些情况持续存在,以及对它们的监管反应失败是本文要解决的问题。我们考察了许多渔业,但重点关注德克萨斯州的虾业,这是美国单一物种最有价值的渔业之一,并且具有在其他地方观察到的共同属性特征。它被认为是资本过剩,单位努力的渔获量正在下降对渔业的考察揭示了地租耗散发生的许多边际,以及控制捕鱼努力以避免这些损失所必需的规章的性质。由于近海和近海渔民之间的渔业冲突,德克萨斯州的监管环境变得复杂。后者断言海湾捕虾减少了成功迁移到海湾的虾的数量。近岸渔业被另一个问题所突出——最近在德克萨斯海岸重新安置了大约30- 4.5万越南难民,其中包括许多渔民(海洋咨询服务,Paul Starr)。他们的进入遭到了现有捕虾人的敌意和暴力,这些捕虾人认识到他们所处的环境的特点是没有财产权。海湾捕虾者游说德克萨斯州立法机关对新进入者进行广泛限制。然而,具有讽刺意味的是,个别捕虾人向越南人出售更多的渔船,为难民进入渔业提供了便利。由于渔民之间的高合同成本和影响政府行为的政治因素,德州虾业和其他渔业的法规不完善,留下了许多不受控制的租金消散选择。不同种类的渔民签约成本很高,他们的差异主要取决于捕鱼技能。3 *分别是蒙大拿州立大学和德州农工大学。我们从Terry Anderson, Raymond C. battio, Gardner Brown, Oscar Burt, Micha Gisser, Wade Griffin, John R. Moroney, Anthony D. Scott, Peter Temin以及德克萨斯州A&M大学和华盛顿大学的研讨会参与者的评论中受益。研究协助由Scott Barnhart和Phil Mizzi提供。资金由德州农工大学Sea Grant提供。在本文中,我们交替使用公共财产和开放获取这两个术语。这里的术语描述了资源不存在产权、团体或个人的情况。2 . W. L. Griffin、C. G. Tydlacka和W. E. Grant给出了1963- 1977年德克萨斯州近海和联邦海湾水域的单位渔获量。它们显示,在近海和近海水域,单位努力的渔获量普遍下降。虽然每单位努力量的捕获量每年都在波动,但从1963年到1977年,它从每单位努力量约360公斤虾下降到220公斤。渔业的共同财产性质反映在以下统计数字中。自1975年以来,船舶数量增长了23%(尼尔森·斯沃茨)。鱼屋的入户记录也是类似的。从1970年到1977年,公司的数量从259家增长到287家,尽管在此期间,许多公司随着其他公司的进入而离开了这个行业。鱼屋的数量是根据德克萨斯州公园和野生动物部门提供的许可证数据计算出来的。鱼屋进入的记录表明,正如科林·克拉克和戈登·门罗所讨论的那样,垄断在渔业中并不存在。在劳动休闲选择和资本方面可能存在细微差异,但我们的统计证据和与渔民的讨论表明,渔获量的变化主要是由于技能。德州海湾的政府法规限制资本,我们的经验证据表明,船只相对同质化。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信