Comment

Tommaso Monacelli
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Tommaso Monacelli","doi":"10.1086/658313","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The main idea of this (very nice) paper is that taxes can be a long-run driver of labor productivity. This raises an intriguing hypothesis: could it be that a recent structural vector autogression (SVAR) based empirical literature that finds that positive innovations in labor productivity have a negative effect on hours workedmay be actually picking up the effects of taxes rather than technology per se? A first issue concerns the question,which taxes? InMertens andRavn’s paper, it is general income taxes. But an immediate implication of a standard neoclassical growth model is that it is only capital income taxes that affect labor productivity in the long run. Hence in principle we should measure capital income taxes as distinct from labor income taxes. In the following I use data from Chen, İmrohoroğlu, and İmrohoroğlu (2009), who extend McGrattan and Prescott’s (2009) measures of capital and labor taxes. Figure 1 shows that the long-run behavior of these two types of taxes has been in fact radically different. Even within capital income taxes, however, and as emphasized by McGrattan and Prescott (2009), it is important to distinguish between three types: (i) taxes on corporate income, (ii) taxes on corporate distributions, and (iii) investment tax credits. McGrattan and Prescott show that, in the 1990s, it is mostly the second category of taxes that has undergone major variations: on average, from 41.1% to 17.4%. Measuring capital and labor tax shocks. To the extent that capital and/or labor income tax changes are believed to be permanent, their first differences should follow random walk processes of the form Δτk;t 1⁄4 εn;t; Δτn;t 1⁄4 εk;t;","PeriodicalId":353207,"journal":{"name":"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics","volume":"84 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2011-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1086/658313","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

The main idea of this (very nice) paper is that taxes can be a long-run driver of labor productivity. This raises an intriguing hypothesis: could it be that a recent structural vector autogression (SVAR) based empirical literature that finds that positive innovations in labor productivity have a negative effect on hours workedmay be actually picking up the effects of taxes rather than technology per se? A first issue concerns the question,which taxes? InMertens andRavn’s paper, it is general income taxes. But an immediate implication of a standard neoclassical growth model is that it is only capital income taxes that affect labor productivity in the long run. Hence in principle we should measure capital income taxes as distinct from labor income taxes. In the following I use data from Chen, İmrohoroğlu, and İmrohoroğlu (2009), who extend McGrattan and Prescott’s (2009) measures of capital and labor taxes. Figure 1 shows that the long-run behavior of these two types of taxes has been in fact radically different. Even within capital income taxes, however, and as emphasized by McGrattan and Prescott (2009), it is important to distinguish between three types: (i) taxes on corporate income, (ii) taxes on corporate distributions, and (iii) investment tax credits. McGrattan and Prescott show that, in the 1990s, it is mostly the second category of taxes that has undergone major variations: on average, from 41.1% to 17.4%. Measuring capital and labor tax shocks. To the extent that capital and/or labor income tax changes are believed to be permanent, their first differences should follow random walk processes of the form Δτk;t 1⁄4 εn;t; Δτn;t 1⁄4 εk;t;
评论
这篇(非常好的)论文的主要思想是,税收可以成为劳动生产率的长期驱动力。这就提出了一个有趣的假设:最近一项基于结构向量渐进(SVAR)的实证文献发现,劳动生产率的积极创新对工作时间有负面影响,这可能实际上是税收的影响,而不是技术本身的影响?第一个问题是,哪些税?在mertens和ravn的论文中,它是一般所得税。但标准的新古典增长模型的直接含义是,从长远来看,只有资本所得税会影响劳动生产率。因此,原则上我们应该将资本所得税与劳动所得税区分开来。在下文中,我使用了Chen, İmrohoroğlu和İmrohoroğlu(2009)的数据,他们扩展了McGrattan和Prescott(2009)的资本和劳动税措施。图1显示了这两种税收的长期行为实际上是完全不同的。然而,即使在资本所得税中,正如McGrattan和Prescott(2009)所强调的那样,区分三种类型是很重要的:(i)企业所得税,(ii)企业分配税,(iii)投资税收抵免。麦格拉坦和普雷斯科特表明,在20世纪90年代,主要是第二类税收发生了重大变化:平均从41.1%到17.4%。衡量资本和劳动税冲击。在某种程度上,资本和/或劳动所得税的变化被认为是永久性的,它们的第一个差异应该遵循如下形式的随机游走过程Δτk;t 1⁄4 εn;t;1 / 4 εk;t;
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信