The New Law and Economic Development: The Future of Law and Development: Second-Generation Reforms and the Incorporation of the Social

Kerry Rittich
{"title":"The New Law and Economic Development: The Future of Law and Development: Second-Generation Reforms and the Incorporation of the Social","authors":"Kerry Rittich","doi":"10.1017/CBO9780511754425.006","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"level but which become clear by focusing not only on efficiency, but on the full range of things rules and institutions actually do. An important part of the task is simply to illustrate the point made at the outset, which is that legal norms and institutions operate in multiple modes: normative, distributive, constitutive, and disciplinary. Another is to observe that the rules that govern economic transactions in industrialized states have always served multiple functions the enhancement of efficiency is but one. To reduce the focus of the reform of legal rules and institutions to concerns about efficiency and market failures, even assuming that the calculus that underpins these efforts is adequate,130 is to miss many of their other properties and effects and to radically reduce in scope the aspirations driving legal regulation. Using historical or genealogical, doctrinal, sociolegal, and other analyses, legal scholars can assist in demonstrating how and why the associations between some institutions and both economic growth and social justice may be unsafe, only loosely connected, largely contingent or alternatively more plausible and robust in any particular context. But above all, such analyses can disclose how they are variable and contested. This, in turn, might provoke a reconsideration of the status both of the rules and institutions that are in vogue and those that are currently discredited. In addition, a historical perspective of any substantial duration is likely to trouble the static image oflaw that often prevails in development debates, illustrates the dynamic, unstable, and transitory nature of legal forms, and suggests the reasons that legal rules and institutions might be viewed as a contingent settlement of interests, values, and concerns. However, legal scholars are also in a position to point out possible synergies between the two sides of the agenda that may exist via different institutional reforms. They may also observe internal conflicts in the commitment to economic agenda itself that remain invisible because of the ideological commitment to the current reform agenda. It is very unclear, for example, that better aggregate economic effects are necessarily generated by the \"deregulated\" labor markets the IFIs now favor; it is almost certainly true that categorical claims about their effects cannot be maintained across the board. But the argument also cuts in the other direction: such analyses might also remind those wedded to social justice through human rights or equality claims that social agendas can be furthered in a variety of ways, and that rights, even if institutionalized in particular ways, are no guarantee of progressive outcomes, particularly in the widely varying contexts in which they are now expected to operate. 130 There are powerful analyses that suggest how and why both the standard modes of assessing efficiency within the IFIs and the association of efficiency enhancement with particular institutional forms and practices might be inadequate. See, for example, Deakin and Wikinson, supra note 54; Elson, supra note 52. The Future of Law and Development 251 As described earlier, rules and institutions may be designed to provide basic levels of security or protection to particular classes or to society in general; labor and employment standards, such as minimum wage laws or health and safety standards are an example of the first, while consumer protection laws stand as an example of the second. Or, like collective bargaining laws, their explicit purpose may be to redress the balance of power among the contracting parties that would obtain in their absence and to alter the sources of rule-making authority in the context of work and production. Like environmental and consumer protection laws, they may be designed to shift the allocation of risk and/ or compel parties to internalize costs that they could otherwise impose on others. Like zoning laws, by allocating different activities to different places, they may literally help constitute the urban geography of societies, chart the direction of future growth and simultaneously influence the fortunes of different groupS.131 While all of these rules and institutions may be efficient as well, efficiency is not necessarily their primary function or effect. Rather, they may be designed to redistribute power and authority. Conversely, even rules that are designed to further efficiency typically generate myriad distributional consequences, consequences that may be both unexpected and far reaching. As these possibilities are often underestimated, one task is to relentlessly document, in both general and more specific ways, the distributive stakes of governance and legal reform projects advanced by the IFls, whether first or second generation or both and whether advanced in the name of the rule of law, efficiency, equality, human rights, labor market justice, or any other value or end.132 There is clearly similar work to be done on the legal reform agendas promoted by social justice constituencies toO.133 This form of analysis helps shift the focus from the projected, overall consequences of reforms in the long term to their more proximate effects on different sectors and populations. (Who or what constitutes the object of concern is a political question in and of themselves, the answer to which will vary from context to context.) It may also help explain why even the expected aggregate effects often fail to materialize. At minimum, this should help provoke reflection on the fact that tradeoffs among different objectives and different fates for different groups may be just as likely as seamlessly coterminous progress on both the macroeconomic and social fronts. By highlighting, rather than suppressing, the fact that winners and losers are to be expected, such analysis should also provoke debate over whether their 131 G ERALD E. FRUG, CITY-MAKING: BUILDING COMMUNITIES WITHOUT BUILDING WALLS (2001). 132 For one effort to engage in this type of analysis with respect to first generation reforms, see Rittich, supra note 9. 133 For an exemplary analysis of the ways that strategies to promote gender equality might work at cross purposes with the interests of other marginalized or disadvantaged groups, see the discussion by Janet Halley in Brenda Cossman, Dan Danielsen, Janet Halley and Tracy Higgins, Gender, Sexuality, and Power: Is Feminist Theory Enough?, 12 COLUM, J. GENDER & 1. 601 (2004) .","PeriodicalId":331401,"journal":{"name":"Michigan Journal of International Law","volume":"18 11 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"96","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Michigan Journal of International Law","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511754425.006","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 96

Abstract

level but which become clear by focusing not only on efficiency, but on the full range of things rules and institutions actually do. An important part of the task is simply to illustrate the point made at the outset, which is that legal norms and institutions operate in multiple modes: normative, distributive, constitutive, and disciplinary. Another is to observe that the rules that govern economic transactions in industrialized states have always served multiple functions the enhancement of efficiency is but one. To reduce the focus of the reform of legal rules and institutions to concerns about efficiency and market failures, even assuming that the calculus that underpins these efforts is adequate,130 is to miss many of their other properties and effects and to radically reduce in scope the aspirations driving legal regulation. Using historical or genealogical, doctrinal, sociolegal, and other analyses, legal scholars can assist in demonstrating how and why the associations between some institutions and both economic growth and social justice may be unsafe, only loosely connected, largely contingent or alternatively more plausible and robust in any particular context. But above all, such analyses can disclose how they are variable and contested. This, in turn, might provoke a reconsideration of the status both of the rules and institutions that are in vogue and those that are currently discredited. In addition, a historical perspective of any substantial duration is likely to trouble the static image oflaw that often prevails in development debates, illustrates the dynamic, unstable, and transitory nature of legal forms, and suggests the reasons that legal rules and institutions might be viewed as a contingent settlement of interests, values, and concerns. However, legal scholars are also in a position to point out possible synergies between the two sides of the agenda that may exist via different institutional reforms. They may also observe internal conflicts in the commitment to economic agenda itself that remain invisible because of the ideological commitment to the current reform agenda. It is very unclear, for example, that better aggregate economic effects are necessarily generated by the "deregulated" labor markets the IFIs now favor; it is almost certainly true that categorical claims about their effects cannot be maintained across the board. But the argument also cuts in the other direction: such analyses might also remind those wedded to social justice through human rights or equality claims that social agendas can be furthered in a variety of ways, and that rights, even if institutionalized in particular ways, are no guarantee of progressive outcomes, particularly in the widely varying contexts in which they are now expected to operate. 130 There are powerful analyses that suggest how and why both the standard modes of assessing efficiency within the IFIs and the association of efficiency enhancement with particular institutional forms and practices might be inadequate. See, for example, Deakin and Wikinson, supra note 54; Elson, supra note 52. The Future of Law and Development 251 As described earlier, rules and institutions may be designed to provide basic levels of security or protection to particular classes or to society in general; labor and employment standards, such as minimum wage laws or health and safety standards are an example of the first, while consumer protection laws stand as an example of the second. Or, like collective bargaining laws, their explicit purpose may be to redress the balance of power among the contracting parties that would obtain in their absence and to alter the sources of rule-making authority in the context of work and production. Like environmental and consumer protection laws, they may be designed to shift the allocation of risk and/ or compel parties to internalize costs that they could otherwise impose on others. Like zoning laws, by allocating different activities to different places, they may literally help constitute the urban geography of societies, chart the direction of future growth and simultaneously influence the fortunes of different groupS.131 While all of these rules and institutions may be efficient as well, efficiency is not necessarily their primary function or effect. Rather, they may be designed to redistribute power and authority. Conversely, even rules that are designed to further efficiency typically generate myriad distributional consequences, consequences that may be both unexpected and far reaching. As these possibilities are often underestimated, one task is to relentlessly document, in both general and more specific ways, the distributive stakes of governance and legal reform projects advanced by the IFls, whether first or second generation or both and whether advanced in the name of the rule of law, efficiency, equality, human rights, labor market justice, or any other value or end.132 There is clearly similar work to be done on the legal reform agendas promoted by social justice constituencies toO.133 This form of analysis helps shift the focus from the projected, overall consequences of reforms in the long term to their more proximate effects on different sectors and populations. (Who or what constitutes the object of concern is a political question in and of themselves, the answer to which will vary from context to context.) It may also help explain why even the expected aggregate effects often fail to materialize. At minimum, this should help provoke reflection on the fact that tradeoffs among different objectives and different fates for different groups may be just as likely as seamlessly coterminous progress on both the macroeconomic and social fronts. By highlighting, rather than suppressing, the fact that winners and losers are to be expected, such analysis should also provoke debate over whether their 131 G ERALD E. FRUG, CITY-MAKING: BUILDING COMMUNITIES WITHOUT BUILDING WALLS (2001). 132 For one effort to engage in this type of analysis with respect to first generation reforms, see Rittich, supra note 9. 133 For an exemplary analysis of the ways that strategies to promote gender equality might work at cross purposes with the interests of other marginalized or disadvantaged groups, see the discussion by Janet Halley in Brenda Cossman, Dan Danielsen, Janet Halley and Tracy Higgins, Gender, Sexuality, and Power: Is Feminist Theory Enough?, 12 COLUM, J. GENDER & 1. 601 (2004) .
新法律与经济发展:法律与发展的未来:第二代改革与社会的整合
水平,但这一点变得清晰,不仅关注效率,而且关注规则和制度实际做的所有事情。这项任务的一个重要部分就是简单地说明一开始提出的观点,即法律规范和制度以多种模式运作:规范性、分配性、构成性和纪律性。另一个是观察到在工业化国家管理经济交易的规则总是具有多种功能,提高效率只是其中之一。将法律规则和制度改革的重点减少到对效率和市场失灵的关注上,即使假设支撑这些努力的微积分是足够的,130也会错过它们的许多其他属性和效果,并从根本上减少推动法律监管的愿望的范围。通过对历史或宗谱、理论、社会法律和其他方面的分析,法律学者可以帮助证明某些制度与经济增长和社会正义之间的联系是如何以及为什么可能是不安全的,只是松散地联系在一起,很大程度上是偶然的,或者在任何特定背景下都更可信和强大。但最重要的是,这种分析可以揭示它们是如何变化和有争议的。反过来,这可能会促使人们重新考虑当前流行的规则和制度,以及那些目前不受信任的规则和制度的地位。此外,任何实质性持续时间的历史观点都可能会扰乱在发展辩论中普遍存在的静态形象,说明法律形式的动态、不稳定和短暂性,并提出法律规则和制度可能被视为利益、价值观和关注点的偶然解决方案的原因。然而,法律学者也可以指出,通过不同的制度改革,这两个议程之间可能存在协同效应。他们还可能观察到,由于对当前改革议程的意识形态承诺,对经济议程本身的承诺中存在的内部冲突仍然不可见。例如,目前非常不清楚的是,国际金融机构现在青睐的“去管制”劳动力市场是否一定会产生更好的总体经济效应;几乎可以肯定的是,对它们的影响的断言不可能全面成立。但这一论点也指向了另一个方向:这样的分析可能还会提醒那些通过人权或平等主张来坚持社会正义的人,社会议程可以通过多种方式进一步推进,而权利,即使以特定的方式制度化,也不能保证取得进步的结果,特别是在现在期望它们运作的各种各样的背景下。130 .有强有力的分析表明,国际金融机构内部评估效率的标准模式以及将提高效率与特定体制形式和做法联系起来的方式和原因可能是不够的。例如,见迪肯和威金森,附注54;Elson,上注52。法律和发展的未来251如前所述,规则和制度的设计可以为特定阶层或整个社会提供基本的安全或保护;劳动和就业标准,如最低工资法或健康和安全标准是前者的一个例子,而消费者保护法是后者的一个例子。或者,像集体谈判法一样,它们的明确目的可能是在没有它们的情况下纠正缔约方之间的权力平衡,并改变工作和生产方面制定规则的权力来源。与环境法和消费者保护法一样,这些法律的目的可能是转移风险的分配和/或迫使各方将原本可能强加于他人的成本内部化。像分区法一样,通过把不同的活动分配到不同的地方,它们可能确实有助于构成社会的城市地理,指明未来发展的方向,同时影响不同群体的命运虽然所有这些规则和制度也可能是有效的,但效率不一定是它们的主要功能或效果。相反,它们的设计可能是为了重新分配权力和权威。相反,即使是旨在提高效率的规则,通常也会产生无数的分配后果,这些后果可能是意想不到的,而且影响深远。由于这些可能性往往被低估,一项任务是坚持不懈地以一般和更具体的方式记录国际金融机构推进的治理和法律改革项目的分配利益,无论是第一代还是第二代,还是两者兼而有之,无论是以法治、效率、平等、人权、劳动力市场正义或任何其他价值或目的的名义推进。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信