Minority Shareholder Protection in SMEs: A Question of Information Ex Post and Bargaining Power Ex Ante?

J. Andersson
{"title":"Minority Shareholder Protection in SMEs: A Question of Information Ex Post and Bargaining Power Ex Ante?","authors":"J. Andersson","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1716828","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"SMEs or, as they are called here, ‘close corporations’, differ in many respects from publicly traded companies. Shares in publicly traded companies have a regulated market which shares in SMEs do not have. Since there is no regulated market for the shares there is usually a lock-in effect in the sense that, in the absence of contractual terms or rules in company law or in the articles of association, (minority) shareholders cannot sell their shares because of the lack of a market or at least they cannot sell them on ‘fair terms’. Furthermore, I suggest that the historical theoretical assumption behind most of the rules in company law in general on protection of the minority is that minority shareholders should only have protection equivalent to their share of the voting rights and/or capital in the company. However, for efficiency reasons, I believe that most minority rules based on this assumption fail to achieve their purpose, namely the protection of the minority in close corporations. The reason for this is that any minority protection based on proportional protection will put the minority shareholders in a relatively weaker position than the proportional rights of those shareholders. To achieve the intended minority protection, I believe the following two conditions have to be met. First, where a particular transaction or event discriminates against a minority shareholder (or shareholders), protection for minority shareholders can only be achieved after the transaction or event, and only if the minority shareholders have access to information equal to or at least similar to a hypothetical perfect market situation (a perfect information position). Second, minority shareholders who do have access to information equal to or at least similar to a hypothetical perfect market situation will be in a bargaining position based on the same information. However, even with this information, minority shareholders will be at a bargaining disadvantage vis-a-vis majority shareholders. The reason is that the position of a minority shareholder in a close corporation, as reflected in the minority share of the voting rights and/or capital, is a bargaining disadvantage in itself. Only by strengthening the relatively weaker bargaining position of the minority shareholders after a discriminatory situation, but prior to negotiations between the minority shareholders and the majority shareholders to negate the discriminatory behaviour, will there be a solution that is proportional to the minority shareholders’ share of the voting rights and/or capital in the company (as well as others interests of minority shareholders in a close corporation, to the extent these can be protected by law). Hence, the minority shareholders’ weaker bargaining position has to be strengthened by minimum legal rules and a right to opt in to a higher level of protection in the articles of association.","PeriodicalId":202300,"journal":{"name":"Nordic & European Company Law Working Paper Series","volume":"27 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2010-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"3","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Nordic & European Company Law Working Paper Series","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1716828","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3

Abstract

SMEs or, as they are called here, ‘close corporations’, differ in many respects from publicly traded companies. Shares in publicly traded companies have a regulated market which shares in SMEs do not have. Since there is no regulated market for the shares there is usually a lock-in effect in the sense that, in the absence of contractual terms or rules in company law or in the articles of association, (minority) shareholders cannot sell their shares because of the lack of a market or at least they cannot sell them on ‘fair terms’. Furthermore, I suggest that the historical theoretical assumption behind most of the rules in company law in general on protection of the minority is that minority shareholders should only have protection equivalent to their share of the voting rights and/or capital in the company. However, for efficiency reasons, I believe that most minority rules based on this assumption fail to achieve their purpose, namely the protection of the minority in close corporations. The reason for this is that any minority protection based on proportional protection will put the minority shareholders in a relatively weaker position than the proportional rights of those shareholders. To achieve the intended minority protection, I believe the following two conditions have to be met. First, where a particular transaction or event discriminates against a minority shareholder (or shareholders), protection for minority shareholders can only be achieved after the transaction or event, and only if the minority shareholders have access to information equal to or at least similar to a hypothetical perfect market situation (a perfect information position). Second, minority shareholders who do have access to information equal to or at least similar to a hypothetical perfect market situation will be in a bargaining position based on the same information. However, even with this information, minority shareholders will be at a bargaining disadvantage vis-a-vis majority shareholders. The reason is that the position of a minority shareholder in a close corporation, as reflected in the minority share of the voting rights and/or capital, is a bargaining disadvantage in itself. Only by strengthening the relatively weaker bargaining position of the minority shareholders after a discriminatory situation, but prior to negotiations between the minority shareholders and the majority shareholders to negate the discriminatory behaviour, will there be a solution that is proportional to the minority shareholders’ share of the voting rights and/or capital in the company (as well as others interests of minority shareholders in a close corporation, to the extent these can be protected by law). Hence, the minority shareholders’ weaker bargaining position has to be strengthened by minimum legal rules and a right to opt in to a higher level of protection in the articles of association.
中小企业中小股东保护:信息事后与事前议价能力问题?
中小企业,也就是这里所说的“封闭式公司”,在许多方面与上市公司不同。上市公司的股票有一个受监管的市场,而中小企业的股票则没有。由于没有受监管的股票市场,因此通常存在一种锁定效应,即在公司法或公司章程中缺乏合同条款或规则的情况下,(少数)股东不能因为缺乏市场而出售他们的股票,或者至少他们不能以“公平的条件”出售股票。此外,我认为,一般公司法中大多数关于保护少数股东的规则背后的历史理论假设是,少数股东应该只享有相当于其在公司的投票权和/或资本份额的保护。然而,出于效率原因,我认为大多数基于这一假设的少数人规则未能达到其目的,即保护封闭公司中的少数人。这是因为,以比例保护为基础的少数股东保护,相对于少数股东的比例权利,会使少数股东处于相对弱势的地位。要实现预期的少数群体保护,我认为必须满足以下两个条件。首先,如果某一特定交易或事件歧视少数股东(或多个股东),那么对少数股东的保护只能在交易或事件发生后才能实现,并且只有当少数股东能够获得等同于或至少类似于假设的完美市场情况(完美信息地位)的信息时才能实现。其次,少数股东确实能够获得与假设的完美市场情况相同或至少类似的信息,他们将基于相同的信息处于讨价还价的地位。然而,即使有了这些信息,相对于大股东,小股东在议价时仍处于劣势。其原因是,在一个封闭的公司中,少数股东的地位,反映在少数股东的投票权和/或资本上,本身就是一个讨价还价的劣势。只有在歧视情况发生后,在少数股东与大股东进行谈判以否定歧视行为之前,加强少数股东相对较弱的议价地位,才会有一个与少数股东在公司中的投票权和/或资本份额(以及少数股东在封闭公司中的其他利益)成比例的解决方案。在法律保护的范围内)。因此,中小股东较弱的议价地位必须通过最低限度的法律规则和在公司章程中选择更高层次保护的权利来加强。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信