Competition in Information Technologies: Standards-Essential Patents, Non-Practicing Entities and FRAND Bidding

Herbert Hovenkamp
{"title":"Competition in Information Technologies: Standards-Essential Patents, Non-Practicing Entities and FRAND Bidding","authors":"Herbert Hovenkamp","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2154203","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Standard Setting is omnipresent in networked information technologies. Virtually every cellular phone, computer, digital camera or similar device contains technologies governed by a collaboratively developed standard. If these technologies are to perform competitively, the processes by which standards are developed and implemented must be competitive. In this case attaining competitive results requires a mixture of antitrust and non-antitrust legal tools. FRAND refers to a firm’s ex ante commitment to make its technology available at a “fair, reasonable and nondiscriminatory royalty.” The FRAND commitment results from bidding to have one’s own technology selected as a standard. Typically the FRAND commitment is not a promise to charge any particular price, but only a price that meets FRAND expectations. This permits members of a standard setting organization (SSO) to focus on technical issues and worry about the price later. Two important questions that a FRAND commitment typically leaves open is the royalty base and the royalty rate. A strong case can be made that the base should be the smallest saleable unit containing the patented technology. While that base is not entirely free from problems, it does provide a more-or-less common currency. The FRAND obligation that the rate be nondiscriminatory typically, but not always, provides a set of yardsticks for measuring the rate. The non-practicing entity (NPE) that voluntarily declines to participate in an SSO process should generally be held to the FRAND royalty as its measure of its damages, even though its particular patents are not FRAND-encumbered. In this case a “reasonable” royalty is the royalty that the patent holder would have obtained in the competitive market in which it might have participated. The case for limiting NPE damages in this way is strongest when the NPE had actual or objectively reasonable knowledge of the SSO process but declined to participate. The case is weakest when the SSO’s processes were not well communicated to outsiders or the NPE in question was not permitted to participate. FRAND commitments should “run with the patent,” in the sense that owners of FRAND-encumbered patents should not be able to free them simply by assigning the patents to someone else. One fundamental principle of property law is that a property owner cannot transfer away a larger interest than it owns. The entire FRAND commitment process would be worthless if patent holders were able to evade it by the simple device of assigning encumbered patents in order to remove the encumbrance. The question of injunctive relief is only a little more complex. A FRAND commitment is on its face an offer to license to all who employ that patent in their standards-compatible product. True, the precise royalty terms are typically not specified in advance, but that entails that the FRAND royalty will be determined by reference to common indicia such as rates paid for similar technologies in the same or perhaps another situation. Further, the FRAND commitment effectively turns the royalty issues into a breach of contract claim rather than a litigated royalty claim. Permitting the owner of a FRAND-encumbered patent to have an injunction against someone willing to pay FRAND royalties is tantamount to making the patent holder the dictator of the royalties, which once again is the same thing as no FRAND commitment at all.","PeriodicalId":162065,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Law & Economics: Private Law (Topic)","volume":"34 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2012-10-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"4","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"LSN: Law & Economics: Private Law (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2154203","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4

Abstract

Standard Setting is omnipresent in networked information technologies. Virtually every cellular phone, computer, digital camera or similar device contains technologies governed by a collaboratively developed standard. If these technologies are to perform competitively, the processes by which standards are developed and implemented must be competitive. In this case attaining competitive results requires a mixture of antitrust and non-antitrust legal tools. FRAND refers to a firm’s ex ante commitment to make its technology available at a “fair, reasonable and nondiscriminatory royalty.” The FRAND commitment results from bidding to have one’s own technology selected as a standard. Typically the FRAND commitment is not a promise to charge any particular price, but only a price that meets FRAND expectations. This permits members of a standard setting organization (SSO) to focus on technical issues and worry about the price later. Two important questions that a FRAND commitment typically leaves open is the royalty base and the royalty rate. A strong case can be made that the base should be the smallest saleable unit containing the patented technology. While that base is not entirely free from problems, it does provide a more-or-less common currency. The FRAND obligation that the rate be nondiscriminatory typically, but not always, provides a set of yardsticks for measuring the rate. The non-practicing entity (NPE) that voluntarily declines to participate in an SSO process should generally be held to the FRAND royalty as its measure of its damages, even though its particular patents are not FRAND-encumbered. In this case a “reasonable” royalty is the royalty that the patent holder would have obtained in the competitive market in which it might have participated. The case for limiting NPE damages in this way is strongest when the NPE had actual or objectively reasonable knowledge of the SSO process but declined to participate. The case is weakest when the SSO’s processes were not well communicated to outsiders or the NPE in question was not permitted to participate. FRAND commitments should “run with the patent,” in the sense that owners of FRAND-encumbered patents should not be able to free them simply by assigning the patents to someone else. One fundamental principle of property law is that a property owner cannot transfer away a larger interest than it owns. The entire FRAND commitment process would be worthless if patent holders were able to evade it by the simple device of assigning encumbered patents in order to remove the encumbrance. The question of injunctive relief is only a little more complex. A FRAND commitment is on its face an offer to license to all who employ that patent in their standards-compatible product. True, the precise royalty terms are typically not specified in advance, but that entails that the FRAND royalty will be determined by reference to common indicia such as rates paid for similar technologies in the same or perhaps another situation. Further, the FRAND commitment effectively turns the royalty issues into a breach of contract claim rather than a litigated royalty claim. Permitting the owner of a FRAND-encumbered patent to have an injunction against someone willing to pay FRAND royalties is tantamount to making the patent holder the dictator of the royalties, which once again is the same thing as no FRAND commitment at all.
信息技术中的竞争:标准必要专利、非执业实体和FRAND招标
标准制定在网络信息技术中无处不在。实际上,每一部手机、电脑、数码相机或类似的设备都包含由合作开发的标准管理的技术。如果要使这些技术具有竞争力,则开发和实施标准的过程必须具有竞争力。在这种情况下,获得竞争性结果需要反垄断和非反垄断法律工具的混合。FRAND指的是公司事先承诺以“公平、合理和非歧视的版税”提供其技术。FRAND承诺是通过竞标将自己的技术选为标准而产生的。通常情况下,FRAND承诺不是承诺收取任何特定价格,而是只收取符合FRAND预期的价格。这使得标准设置组织(SSO)的成员可以专注于技术问题,稍后再考虑价格问题。FRAND承诺通常会留下两个重要的问题,即版税基数和版税费率。可以强有力地证明,所述底座应是包含该专利技术的最小可销售单元。虽然这个基础并非完全没有问题,但它确实提供了一种或多或少的通用货币。FRAND要求税率不具有歧视性的义务通常(但并非总是)提供了一套衡量税率的标准。自愿拒绝参与SSO过程的非执业实体(NPE)通常应被视为对其损害的衡量标准,即使其特定专利不受rand妨碍。在这种情况下,“合理的”特许权使用费是专利权人在其可能参与的竞争市场中获得的特许权使用费。当NPE对SSO过程有实际或客观合理的了解,但拒绝参与时,以这种方式限制NPE损害的案例是最有力的。当SSO的流程没有很好地与外部沟通,或者相关的NPE不被允许参与时,这种情况最弱。FRAND承诺应该“与专利一起运行”,从某种意义上说,受FRAND拖累的专利的所有者不应该仅仅通过将专利转让给其他人来释放它们。物权法的一个基本原则是,财产所有人不能转让比其拥有的更大的利益。如果专利持有人能够通过转让障碍专利以消除障碍的简单手段来规避它,那么整个FRAND承诺过程将毫无价值。禁令救济的问题只是稍微复杂一点。从表面上看,FRAND承诺是向所有在其标准兼容产品中使用该专利的人提供许可。诚然,准确的特许权使用费条款通常没有事先规定,但这意味着FRAND特许权使用费将根据共同指标确定,例如在相同或可能另一种情况下为类似技术支付的费用。此外,FRAND承诺有效地将特许权使用费问题转化为违约索赔,而不是诉讼特许权使用费索赔。允许受FRAND限制的专利所有人对愿意支付FRAND特许权使用费的人发出禁令,等于让专利持有人成为特许权使用费的独裁者,这再次与根本没有FRAND承诺是一样的。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信