Political economy of state homeland security grants

Michael J. Dueker, Christopher J. Martinek
{"title":"Political economy of state homeland security grants","authors":"Michael J. Dueker, Christopher J. Martinek","doi":"10.20955/es.2006.29","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"On October 4, 2006, President Bush signed the Department of Homeland Security (DHS) Appro pri ations Act for fiscal year 2007. The law provides $525 million for state homeland security grants and, as in previous years, allocates the funds according to a formula written into law by the Patriot Act. This formula guarantees each state 0.75 percent of the total funds appropriated in a fiscal year for state and local terrorism preparedness grants. In the initial years of the program, the allocation of remaining funds was left to the discretion of the DHS, which distributed the remaining funds according to each state’s share of the national population. In June 2004, the 9/11 Commission report recommended against the population-based distribution of these grants. The Commission favored instead an allocation based on risk and vulnerability. Critics of the state grant formula pointed to Wyoming’s total grant receipts per capita, which were the largest among all states because Wyoming has the smallest share of national population. In contrast, states such as California and New York, with a presumably greater terrorist threat, received much less per capita funding. The U.S. House and Senate responded to the 9/11 Commission by seeking to base state grant levels more on risk assessments and less on population, while still guaranteeing a minimum share to each state. The distinct House and Senate proposals serve as a case study in political economy, in the way political bodies seek to allocate economic resources. The House bill proposed a state minimum allocation of 0.25 percent; the Senate bill proposed 0.55 percent. These numbers are interesting: In the House, each state has a minimum voting share of 1/435 or 0.23 percent of the representatives. In the Senate, the allocation of two senators for each state, regardless of population, increases the relative representation for small states in the full U.S. Congress to a minimum of 3/535 or 0.56 percent. It is remarkable how close these two percentages are to the minimum allocations that the House and Senate proposed. Political economy considerations would suggest that the median voter on this issue in the Senate would be from a state with below-average population—hence, the relatively generous 0.55 percent minimum share. In conference committee, however, the House and Senate did not agree on whether or how to amend the Patriot Act, so each state’s 0.75 percent minimum share has remained intact. Instead, the House and Senate decided to cut the size of the state grant program, both in its share of DHS spending and in absolute terms. In addition, the state grant funds not committed by the minimum guaranteed levels are to be distributed according to risk and not simply population. Accordingly, the attached chart shows how per capita grants to the states shifted between 2005 and 2006. The distribution of per capita grants across states became much more concentrated in the range of $1 to $3 per capita in 2006 and grants above $13 were eliminated by reducing the program’s overall funding. Congress may have wanted to reduce the per capita grants to the smallest states (seen as an excessive amount by some) from about $18 to about $13 (about 30 percent). This reduction in funding to the state grant program achieved roughly the same result for the smallest states that the change from a 0.75 percent to a 0.55 percent minimum share would have achieved. Total spending on homeland security was not cut as drastically as the state grants; instead, Congress chose to channel resources through alternative programs not subject to the 0.75 percent minimum share per state. Political Economy of State Homeland Security Grants","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"95 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"National Economic Trends","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2006.29","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

On October 4, 2006, President Bush signed the Department of Homeland Security (DHS) Appro pri ations Act for fiscal year 2007. The law provides $525 million for state homeland security grants and, as in previous years, allocates the funds according to a formula written into law by the Patriot Act. This formula guarantees each state 0.75 percent of the total funds appropriated in a fiscal year for state and local terrorism preparedness grants. In the initial years of the program, the allocation of remaining funds was left to the discretion of the DHS, which distributed the remaining funds according to each state’s share of the national population. In June 2004, the 9/11 Commission report recommended against the population-based distribution of these grants. The Commission favored instead an allocation based on risk and vulnerability. Critics of the state grant formula pointed to Wyoming’s total grant receipts per capita, which were the largest among all states because Wyoming has the smallest share of national population. In contrast, states such as California and New York, with a presumably greater terrorist threat, received much less per capita funding. The U.S. House and Senate responded to the 9/11 Commission by seeking to base state grant levels more on risk assessments and less on population, while still guaranteeing a minimum share to each state. The distinct House and Senate proposals serve as a case study in political economy, in the way political bodies seek to allocate economic resources. The House bill proposed a state minimum allocation of 0.25 percent; the Senate bill proposed 0.55 percent. These numbers are interesting: In the House, each state has a minimum voting share of 1/435 or 0.23 percent of the representatives. In the Senate, the allocation of two senators for each state, regardless of population, increases the relative representation for small states in the full U.S. Congress to a minimum of 3/535 or 0.56 percent. It is remarkable how close these two percentages are to the minimum allocations that the House and Senate proposed. Political economy considerations would suggest that the median voter on this issue in the Senate would be from a state with below-average population—hence, the relatively generous 0.55 percent minimum share. In conference committee, however, the House and Senate did not agree on whether or how to amend the Patriot Act, so each state’s 0.75 percent minimum share has remained intact. Instead, the House and Senate decided to cut the size of the state grant program, both in its share of DHS spending and in absolute terms. In addition, the state grant funds not committed by the minimum guaranteed levels are to be distributed according to risk and not simply population. Accordingly, the attached chart shows how per capita grants to the states shifted between 2005 and 2006. The distribution of per capita grants across states became much more concentrated in the range of $1 to $3 per capita in 2006 and grants above $13 were eliminated by reducing the program’s overall funding. Congress may have wanted to reduce the per capita grants to the smallest states (seen as an excessive amount by some) from about $18 to about $13 (about 30 percent). This reduction in funding to the state grant program achieved roughly the same result for the smallest states that the change from a 0.75 percent to a 0.55 percent minimum share would have achieved. Total spending on homeland security was not cut as drastically as the state grants; instead, Congress chose to channel resources through alternative programs not subject to the 0.75 percent minimum share per state. Political Economy of State Homeland Security Grants
国家国土安全拨款的政治经济学
2006年10月4日,布什总统签署了2007财政年度国土安全部拨款法案。该法案为各州的国土安全拨款提供了5.25亿美元,与往年一样,这笔资金是根据《爱国者法案》(Patriot Act)写入法律的公式分配的。这个公式保证每个州在一个财政年度的总拨款中有0.75%用于州和地方的反恐准备拨款。在项目的最初几年,剩余资金的分配由国土安全部自行决定,国土安全部根据各州占全国人口的比例分配剩余资金。2004年6月,9/11委员会的报告建议反对以人口为基础分配这些补助金。委员会倾向于根据风险和脆弱性进行分配。对州拨款公式持批评态度的人指出,怀俄明州的人均拨款总额是所有州中最高的,因为怀俄明州占全国人口的比例最小。相比之下,加州和纽约州等可能面临更大恐怖主义威胁的州,获得的人均资助要少得多。美国众议院和参议院对911委员会的回应是,寻求更多地以风险评估为基础,而不是以人口为基础,同时仍然保证每个州都有最低份额。参众两院截然不同的提案是政治经济学的一个研究案例,研究政治机构如何分配经济资源。众议院法案提议各州最低拨款为0.25%;参议院法案提出0.55%。这些数字很有趣:在众议院,每个州的最低投票份额为1/435,即0.23%的代表。在参议院,无论人口多少,每个州都分配两名参议员,使小州在美国国会的相对代表性至少增加到3/535或0.56%。值得注意的是,这两个百分比非常接近众议院和参议院提出的最低拨款。从政治经济学角度考虑,参议院在这个问题上的选民中位数将来自人口低于平均水平的州——因此,相对慷慨的0.55%的最低份额。然而,在会议委员会上,参众两院没有就是否或如何修改《爱国者法案》达成一致,因此每个州0.75%的最低份额保持不变。相反,众议院和参议院决定削减国家拨款项目的规模,无论是在国土安全部支出中所占的份额还是在绝对值上。此外,未由最低保证水平承担的国家赠款资金将根据风险而不是简单地根据人口进行分配。因此,所附图表显示了2005年至2006年间各州人均拨款的变化情况。2006年,各州的人均补助金分配更加集中在人均1美元至3美元的范围内,13美元以上的补助金通过减少项目的总体资金而被取消。国会可能想要减少对最小州的人均拨款(有些人认为这是一个过多的数额),从大约18美元减少到大约13美元(大约30%)。对于最小的州来说,减少对州拨款项目的资助所取得的结果与将最低份额从0.75%降低到0.55%所取得的结果大致相同。国土安全的总支出没有像州政府拨款那样大幅削减;相反,国会选择通过不受每个州0.75%最低份额限制的其他项目来分配资源。国家国土安全拨款的政治经济学
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信