Vertical Integration, Institutional Determinants and Impact: Evidence from China

Joseph P. H. Fan, Jun Huang, R. Morck, B. Yeung
{"title":"Vertical Integration, Institutional Determinants and Impact: Evidence from China","authors":"Joseph P. H. Fan, Jun Huang, R. Morck, B. Yeung","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1100335","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Where legal systems and market forces enforce contracts inadequately, vertical integration can circumvent these transaction difficulties. But, such environments often also feature highly interventionist government, and even corruption. Vertical integration might then enhance returns to political rent-seeking aimed at securing and extending market power. Thus, where political rent seeking is minimal, vertical integration should add to firm value and economy performance; but where political rent seeking is substantial, firm value might rise as economy performance decays. China offers a suitable background for empirical examination of these issues because her legal and market institutions are generally weak, but nonetheless exhibit substantial province-level variation. Vertical integration is more common where legal institutions are weaker and where regional governments are of lower quality or more interventionist. In such provinces, firms led by insiders with political connections are more likely to be vertically integrated. Vertical integration is negatively associated with firm value if the top corporate insider is politically connected, but weakly positively associated with public share valuations if the politically connected firm is independently audited. Finally, provinces whose vertical integrated firms tend to have politically unconnected CEOs exhibit elevated per capita GDP growth, while provinces whose vertically integrated firms tend to have political insiders as CEOs exhibit depressed per capita GDP growth.","PeriodicalId":194146,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Firm Behavior (Topic)","volume":"103 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2008-02-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"33","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"ERN: Firm Behavior (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1100335","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 33

Abstract

Where legal systems and market forces enforce contracts inadequately, vertical integration can circumvent these transaction difficulties. But, such environments often also feature highly interventionist government, and even corruption. Vertical integration might then enhance returns to political rent-seeking aimed at securing and extending market power. Thus, where political rent seeking is minimal, vertical integration should add to firm value and economy performance; but where political rent seeking is substantial, firm value might rise as economy performance decays. China offers a suitable background for empirical examination of these issues because her legal and market institutions are generally weak, but nonetheless exhibit substantial province-level variation. Vertical integration is more common where legal institutions are weaker and where regional governments are of lower quality or more interventionist. In such provinces, firms led by insiders with political connections are more likely to be vertically integrated. Vertical integration is negatively associated with firm value if the top corporate insider is politically connected, but weakly positively associated with public share valuations if the politically connected firm is independently audited. Finally, provinces whose vertical integrated firms tend to have politically unconnected CEOs exhibit elevated per capita GDP growth, while provinces whose vertically integrated firms tend to have political insiders as CEOs exhibit depressed per capita GDP growth.
纵向整合、制度决定因素及其影响:来自中国的证据
在法律体系和市场力量无法充分执行合同的地方,垂直整合可以规避这些交易困难。但是,在这样的环境中,往往也有高度干预主义的政府,甚至腐败。然后,垂直一体化可能会提高旨在确保和扩大市场力量的政治寻租的回报。因此,在政治寻租最小的地方,垂直整合应该增加企业价值和经济绩效;但在政治寻租现象严重的地方,随着经济表现的衰退,公司价值可能会上升。中国为这些问题的实证研究提供了一个合适的背景,因为中国的法律和市场制度普遍薄弱,但各省之间的差异仍然很大。在法律制度较弱、地方政府质量较差或干预力度较大的地方,垂直一体化更为常见。在这些省份,由有政治关系的内部人士领导的公司更有可能进行垂直整合。如果公司高层内部人员有政治关系,垂直整合与公司价值呈负相关,但如果有政治关系的公司是独立审计的,垂直整合与上市股票估值呈弱正相关。最后,纵向整合企业ceo与政治无关的省份人均GDP增长较高,而纵向整合企业ceo为政治内部人的省份人均GDP增长较低。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信