Competitive Neutrality of Soes in International Investment Law

C. de Stefano
{"title":"Competitive Neutrality of Soes in International Investment Law","authors":"C. de Stefano","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3209867","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"This paper aims to investigate whether the principle of competitive neutrality of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) may be resorted to by international arbitral tribunals in investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS). This principle posits that the ownership (either public or private) of a given business should not affect its competitive opportunities in the market arena. Although being legally separated from their establishing State, usually independent and autonomous in their self organization, SOEs retain an undeniable vicinity and contact with the public sphere and can and do participate in the exercise of governmental authority at given conditions. This is reflected inter alia by given benefits of SOEs under domestic legal systems such as regulatory immunity from antitrust regulation, fiscal advantages or the exemption from bankruptcy legislation. In ISDS, the mechanism of attribution of conduct of SOEs is generally governed by customary international law, especially as codified by Article 5 of the Draft Articles on Responsibility of States for Internationally Wrongful Acts (ARSIWA), which relies on the divide between governmental and commercial activities, similar to the nature test applied in relation to the defence of jurisdictional immunity of foreign States before domestic courts. In the international arbitral practice, this dichotomy is traditionally based on the “private contractor�? test, which defines as “sovereign�? such activities in which a private party may not engage, and, conversely, as “commercial�? such activities that a private party may perform. Upon resort to competitive neutrality considerations, the “private contractor�? test may be further extended so that the acts that a private competitor in the market arena could have not executed be considered as falling under the exercise of elements of the governmental authority. The principle of competitive neutrality has been elaborated under the aegis of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) through adoption of soft law instruments, such as its ‘Guidelines on Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises’. In addition,the practice of the World Trade Organization (WTO) dispute settlement system (DSS) may also be instructive with regard to the definition of ‘public body’ under Article 1.1(a)(1) of the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM Agreement). The Author supports reliance by arbitrators to the principle of competitive neutrality of SOEs in order to strengthen the scope of the rules of attribution codified by ARSIWA, especially under Article 5, so as to foster the accountability of States and SOEs, also in the eyes of their constituencies, and to level the playing field in markets where SOEs and private undertakings compete.","PeriodicalId":378416,"journal":{"name":"International Economic Law eJournal","volume":"2 4","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2018-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"International Economic Law eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3209867","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

This paper aims to investigate whether the principle of competitive neutrality of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) may be resorted to by international arbitral tribunals in investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS). This principle posits that the ownership (either public or private) of a given business should not affect its competitive opportunities in the market arena. Although being legally separated from their establishing State, usually independent and autonomous in their self organization, SOEs retain an undeniable vicinity and contact with the public sphere and can and do participate in the exercise of governmental authority at given conditions. This is reflected inter alia by given benefits of SOEs under domestic legal systems such as regulatory immunity from antitrust regulation, fiscal advantages or the exemption from bankruptcy legislation. In ISDS, the mechanism of attribution of conduct of SOEs is generally governed by customary international law, especially as codified by Article 5 of the Draft Articles on Responsibility of States for Internationally Wrongful Acts (ARSIWA), which relies on the divide between governmental and commercial activities, similar to the nature test applied in relation to the defence of jurisdictional immunity of foreign States before domestic courts. In the international arbitral practice, this dichotomy is traditionally based on the “private contractor�? test, which defines as “sovereign�? such activities in which a private party may not engage, and, conversely, as “commercial�? such activities that a private party may perform. Upon resort to competitive neutrality considerations, the “private contractor�? test may be further extended so that the acts that a private competitor in the market arena could have not executed be considered as falling under the exercise of elements of the governmental authority. The principle of competitive neutrality has been elaborated under the aegis of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) through adoption of soft law instruments, such as its ‘Guidelines on Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises’. In addition,the practice of the World Trade Organization (WTO) dispute settlement system (DSS) may also be instructive with regard to the definition of ‘public body’ under Article 1.1(a)(1) of the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM Agreement). The Author supports reliance by arbitrators to the principle of competitive neutrality of SOEs in order to strengthen the scope of the rules of attribution codified by ARSIWA, especially under Article 5, so as to foster the accountability of States and SOEs, also in the eyes of their constituencies, and to level the playing field in markets where SOEs and private undertakings compete.
国际投资法中国有企业的竞争中立性
本文旨在探讨国际仲裁庭在投资者与国家争端解决(ISDS)中是否可以采用国有企业竞争中立原则。这一原则假定,给定企业的所有权(无论是公有的还是私有的)不应影响其在市场舞台上的竞争机会。国有企业虽然在法律上与其建立国分离,通常在其自我组织中是独立和自主的,但它们与公共领域保持着不可否认的联系和联系,并且能够而且确实在一定条件下参与政府权力的行使。除其他外,这反映在国有企业在国内法律制度下享有的利益,如对反垄断管制的管制豁免、财政优惠或免于破产立法。在ISDS中,国有企业行为的归因机制一般由习惯国际法管辖,特别是由《国家对国际不法行为的责任条款草案》第5条所规定,它依赖于区分政府活动和商业活动,类似于在国内法院为外国管辖豁免辩护时适用的性质检验标准。在国际仲裁实践中,这种二分法传统上是以“私人承包商”为基础的。测试,它定义为“主权”?这些活动是私人当事人不得参与的,相反,被认为是“商业性的”?私人团体可以进行的活动基于竞争中立的考虑,“私人承包商”?测试可以进一步扩展,以便将市场领域中私人竞争者本不可能执行的行为视为属于政府权力要素的行使。在经济合作与发展组织(OECD)的支持下,通过采用软法律文书,如“国有企业公司治理指南”,详细阐述了竞争中立原则。此外,世界贸易组织(WTO)争端解决机制(DSS)的实践也可能对《补贴与反补贴措施协定》(《SCM协定》)第1.1条(a)款(1)项下的“公共机构”定义具有指导意义。作者支持仲裁员遵循国有企业竞争中立的原则,以加强ARSIWA编纂的归因规则的范围,特别是根据第5条,从而促进国家和国有企业的问责制,也在其选民的眼中,并在国有企业和私营企业竞争的市场中创造公平的竞争环境。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信