A Miser’s Rule of Reason: Student Athlete Compensation and the Alston Antitrust Case

Herbert Hovenkamp
{"title":"A Miser’s Rule of Reason: Student Athlete Compensation and the Alston Antitrust Case","authors":"Herbert Hovenkamp","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3879580","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The unanimous Supreme Court decision in NCAA v. Alston is its most important probe of antitrust’s rule of reason in decades. The decision implicates several issues, including the role of antitrust in labor markets, how antitrust applies to institutions that have an educational mission as well as involvement in a large commercial enterprise, and how much leeway district courts should have in creating decrees that contemplate ongoing administration. The Court accepted what has come to be the accepted framework: the plaintiff must make out a prima facie case of competitive harm. Then the burden shifts to the defendant to produce a justification and, if it produces one, the plaintiff will have a chance to show a less restrictive alternative. While the Court has articulated this three-stage inquiry several times, it has almost always loaded all the important proof requirements into the first stage, with the result that plaintiffs nearly always lose. This is an irrational approach to decision making that reflects a deep anti-enforcement bias. In Alston, however, the plaintiffs finally broke out of that box, but only because the practice itself was a nearly naked cartel. So is the Court now ready to develop a more enforcement-neutral approach to antitrust’s rule of reason? Most rule of reason cases do not involve naked or nearly naked cartels. They are concerned with production or research joint ventures, standard setting, or other agreements whose effects are more complex. Alston was the unique rule of reason case in which the challenged practice was close to a naked cartel. In any other setting it would have been governed by the per se rule but for an idiosyncratic history that compelled the rule of reason. If plaintiffs can successfully navigate the “three-step” rule of reason case only when the challenged restraint is little more than collusion, then the rule of reason is not doing its job. In most rule of reason challenges, including those brought by the government, the plaintiff’s prima facie case depends on market evidence that supports reasonable inferences of competitive harm. By contrast, when the burden shirts, the defense typically depends on evidence about its own conduct and the rationales for it. In terms of decisional quality, cases that raise an inference of competitive harm will be more accurately resolved at the second stage rather than the first one. This does not mean that trivial claims or claims against firms that clearly lack power should go forward. It does suggest, however, that at the first stage the plaintiff should bear a smaller burden.","PeriodicalId":288236,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Theoretical Perspectives on Employment & Labor Law (Topic)","volume":"254 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2021-07-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"LSN: Theoretical Perspectives on Employment & Labor Law (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3879580","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

The unanimous Supreme Court decision in NCAA v. Alston is its most important probe of antitrust’s rule of reason in decades. The decision implicates several issues, including the role of antitrust in labor markets, how antitrust applies to institutions that have an educational mission as well as involvement in a large commercial enterprise, and how much leeway district courts should have in creating decrees that contemplate ongoing administration. The Court accepted what has come to be the accepted framework: the plaintiff must make out a prima facie case of competitive harm. Then the burden shifts to the defendant to produce a justification and, if it produces one, the plaintiff will have a chance to show a less restrictive alternative. While the Court has articulated this three-stage inquiry several times, it has almost always loaded all the important proof requirements into the first stage, with the result that plaintiffs nearly always lose. This is an irrational approach to decision making that reflects a deep anti-enforcement bias. In Alston, however, the plaintiffs finally broke out of that box, but only because the practice itself was a nearly naked cartel. So is the Court now ready to develop a more enforcement-neutral approach to antitrust’s rule of reason? Most rule of reason cases do not involve naked or nearly naked cartels. They are concerned with production or research joint ventures, standard setting, or other agreements whose effects are more complex. Alston was the unique rule of reason case in which the challenged practice was close to a naked cartel. In any other setting it would have been governed by the per se rule but for an idiosyncratic history that compelled the rule of reason. If plaintiffs can successfully navigate the “three-step” rule of reason case only when the challenged restraint is little more than collusion, then the rule of reason is not doing its job. In most rule of reason challenges, including those brought by the government, the plaintiff’s prima facie case depends on market evidence that supports reasonable inferences of competitive harm. By contrast, when the burden shirts, the defense typically depends on evidence about its own conduct and the rationales for it. In terms of decisional quality, cases that raise an inference of competitive harm will be more accurately resolved at the second stage rather than the first one. This does not mean that trivial claims or claims against firms that clearly lack power should go forward. It does suggest, however, that at the first stage the plaintiff should bear a smaller burden.
守财奴的理性法则:学生运动员赔偿与阿尔斯通反托拉斯案
最高法院对NCAA诉阿尔斯通案的一致裁决是几十年来对反垄断理性原则最重要的调查。这一裁决涉及几个问题,包括反垄断在劳动力市场中的作用,反垄断如何适用于既具有教育使命又涉及大型商业企业的机构,以及地方法院在制定考虑持续管理的法令时应该有多大的回旋余地。法院接受了已经被接受的框架:原告必须提出一个初步的竞争性损害案件。然后,责任就转移到被告身上,让他提出正当理由,如果能提出正当理由,原告就有机会提出限制较少的替代方案。虽然最高法院多次阐明了这三个阶段的调查,但它几乎总是把所有重要的证据要求都放在第一阶段,结果几乎总是原告败诉。这是一种非理性的决策方式,反映了一种根深蒂固的反执法偏见。然而,在奥尔斯顿,原告最终打破了这个框框,但只是因为这种做法本身就是一个近乎赤裸裸的卡特尔。那么,最高法院现在是否准备为反垄断的理性规则制定一种更加执法中立的方法呢?大多数理性规则案件不涉及赤裸裸或近乎赤裸裸的卡特尔。它们涉及生产或研究合资企业、标准制定或其他影响更为复杂的协议。阿尔斯通是一个独特的理性规则案例,在这个案例中,受到质疑的做法接近于一个赤裸裸的卡特尔。如果不是特殊的历史迫使理性统治,在任何其他情况下,它都会受到自身规则的支配。如果原告只有在被质疑的限制只不过是共谋的情况下,才能成功地驾驭“三步走”理性规则,那么理性规则就没有发挥它的作用。在大多数理性规则的挑战中,包括那些由政府提出的,原告的初步证据依赖于支持竞争损害的合理推论的市场证据。相比之下,当负担减轻时,辩护通常依赖于有关其自身行为的证据及其理由。在判决质量方面,提出竞争损害推理的案件在第二阶段比在第一阶段得到更准确的裁决。这并不意味着琐碎的索赔或针对明显缺乏权力的公司的索赔应该继续进行。然而,它确实表明,在第一阶段,原告应该承担较小的负担。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信