Falling behind whom? Economic geographies of right-wing populism in Europe

IF 4.6 1区 社会学 Q1 POLITICAL SCIENCE
Dominik Schraff, Jonas Pontusson
{"title":"Falling behind whom? Economic geographies of right-wing populism in Europe","authors":"Dominik Schraff, Jonas Pontusson","doi":"10.1080/13501763.2023.2278647","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTExisting studies suggest that right-wing populist parties (RWPPs) appeal to people in communities that have fallen behind in material terms. However, it remains open which benchmark communities apply as they become politically discontented. We argue that the structure of territorial inequalities influences the benchmarks used by people in regions falling behind. Panel data regressions using subnational election results in EU states from 1990 to 2018 reveal a sharp contrast between the economic geographies of right-wing populism in core and peripheral EU member states. We find a strong association between falling behind the richest region of the country and RWPP support within core EU countries, while in peripheral EU states falling behind the EU core is associated with regional support for RWPPs. This suggests that RWPP voters in peripheral countries cue on how they are faring relative to the EU core, while RWPP supporters in core countries cue on how they are faring relative to dynamic regions of their own country. Our analysis also shows that increased manufacturing employment reinforces the effect of falling behind the richest region in core EU member states, while we find no strong evidence that regional economic stagnation is important to the electoral performance of RWPPs.KEYWORDS: Europegeographyinequalityright-wing populism AcknowledgementsAn earlier version of the paper was presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association (Montreal) in September 2022 and at a workshop at Copenhagen Business School in October 2022. We thank the participants in both events for constructive feedback.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 While SD’s national vote share increased by 2.5 points, its Stockholm vote share increased by less than one percentage point. Statistics Sweden, https://www.scb.se/en/finding-statistics/statistics-by-subject-area/democracy/general-elections/general-elections-results/.2 Dropping the three smallest member states (Luxembourg, Cyprus and Malta) and losing some additional observations for lack of data on independent variables, our analysis is restricted to 1,053 regional units in 25 countries. Regional units are NUTS 3 regions for 19 countries and NUTS 2 regions for 6 countries (Belgium, Ireland, Netherlands, Poland, Slovenia and the UK). Countries that have joined the EU since 1990 enter the dataset the year they obtained the status of an ‘accession country.’ The EU-NED dataset and codebook are available at: https://dataverse.harvard.edu/file.xhtml?fileId=6157990&version=1.13 We consider ‘right-wing’ to be interchangeable with ‘far Right’ and ‘radical Right.’ While many recent studies posit common determinants of left-wing and right-wing populism, Gonthier (Citation2023) as well as Burgoon et al. (Citation2019) emphasise differences in the motivations of individuals who support left-wing and right-wing populist parties.4 It goes without saying that there is an important (inter-)subjective component to social status, but social status should not be conflated with the conflicts over cultural values emphasised by Inglehart and Norris (Citation2019). In our understanding, a ‘materialist account’ does not imply that ‘objective conditions’ suffice to explain support for right-wing populist parties. Notable contributions to the literature that link right-wing populism to divergence in regional economic trajectories include Hobolt (Citation2016), McNamara (Citation2017), Rodríguez-Pose (Citation2018), Essletzbichler et al. (Citation2018), Carreras et al. (Citation2019), Djikstra et al. (Citation2019), Schraff (Citation2019) and Adler and Ansell (Citation2020). See Chou et al. (Citation2022) for a broader discussion of the ‘localist turn’ in the study of populism.5 All parties that we identify as ‘right-wing populist’ are also coded by PopuList as ‘Eurosceptic.’ See Djikstra et al. (Citation2019) for a useful discussion of the overlap between populism and Euroskepticism.6 As documented by Hense and Schäfer (Citation2022), perceptions of not having any political voice are closely associated with voting for RWPPs across European democracies. See Lipps and Schraff (Citation2021) on the effects of regional inequality on trust in national political institutions and EU institutions.7 Other studies that identify differences in public attitudes across the divide between rich and poor EU member states include De Vries (Citation2018), Vasilopoulou and Talving (Citation2020), and Mayne and Katsanidou (Citation2022).8 Analyzing party programmes presented in Land elections, León and Scantamburlo (Citation2022) provide a fascinating case study of how the AfD balances efforts to mobilise regional grievances with appeals to German national identity.9 Our argumentation also draws inspiration from Scase (Citation1977). Building on Runciman (Citation1966), Scase shows convincingly that Swedish manual workers are much more likely to compare themselves to (upper) middle-class individuals than their British counterparts. He attributes the difference between his two samples to the structure of national union movements.10 Note that our conceptualisation of the core-periphery distinction is fundamentally economic and thus different from similar distinctions by students of European integration (e.g., Schimmelfennig, Citation2016). Like the empirical analysis that follows, Table 1 excludes the three smallest EU member states. Luxembourg clearly belongs in the EU core by virtue of its GDP per capita ($131,511 in 2021) as well as being a founding member of the EU. The UK features as a core EU member state because our analysis pertains to the period from 1990 to 2018. Note also that all core member states were richer than all peripheral member states already in 1990.11 ARDECO estimates of regional GDP per capita take purchasing power into account. Source: https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/territorial/ardeco-database_en.12 The rise of regional inequality stands in sharp contrast to stability of personal (‘vertical’) income inequality in the EU core since the financial crisis of 2007–2008: averaging across the ten countries, the top 10 per cent share of pre-tax national income increased by less than 1 per cent from 2006 to 2021 (https://wid.world/). The Swedish case illustrates divergent trends in vertical and horizontal inequalities as well as regional variation in right-wing populist support. As defined by Statistics Sweden, the percentage of adults ‘at risk of poverty’ was 14.2 per cent in metropolitan areas and 14.3 per cent in smaller towns and rural areas in 2010. By 2020, the figure for metropolitan areas had dropped to 11.8 per cent while the figure for smaller towns and rural areas had increased to 20.3 per cent (https://www.statistikdatabasen.scb.se/pxweb/en/ssd/START__LE__LE0101/). Over the same period, the overall Gini coefficient for post-tax national income declined from .31 to .29 (https://wid.world/).13 We prefer a fixed effects specification for the region and year levels rather than random effects as standard error estimates are more conservative. Moreover, there currently are no readily available estimation procedures that allow quasi-binomial link functions in multi-level GLM, as well as a lack of tools to calculate clustered standard errors.14 Our measures of the aforementioned control variables are also based on ARDECO data (https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/territorial/ardeco-database_en). See Appendix 1 for descriptive statistics on all variables included in our analysis.15 Note that there are 11 core countries and 14 peripheral ones, and still the N of the core-country sample is 4,888 and the N of the periphery-country sample 2,588. This is due to the fact the data for richer countries covers a longer time period and that richer countries tend to have more regions (e.g., Germany has around 400 NUTS3 regions).16 The interaction effects reported in Table 4 are estimated using standardised variables and a double-demeaned estimator (Giesselmann & Schmidt-Catran, Citation2022).17 The non-linear patterns at high values of GDP growth in the left-hand panel of Figure 7 result from statistical extrapolation, with very few observations driving these results (see rug plot below the marginal effects).Additional informationFundingDominik Schraff’s work on this paper was supported by an Ambizione Grant from the Swiss National Science Foundation (grant number 186002). Jonas Pontusson’s contribution was funded by the European Research Council under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program (Advanced grant number 741538).Notes on contributorsDominik SchraffDominik Schraff is associate professor of political science at Aalborg University, Denmark.Jonas PontussonJonas Pontusson is professor of political science at the University of Geneva, Switzerland.","PeriodicalId":51362,"journal":{"name":"Journal of European Public Policy","volume":" 8","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":4.6000,"publicationDate":"2023-11-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"3","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of European Public Policy","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2023.2278647","RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"POLITICAL SCIENCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3

Abstract

ABSTRACTExisting studies suggest that right-wing populist parties (RWPPs) appeal to people in communities that have fallen behind in material terms. However, it remains open which benchmark communities apply as they become politically discontented. We argue that the structure of territorial inequalities influences the benchmarks used by people in regions falling behind. Panel data regressions using subnational election results in EU states from 1990 to 2018 reveal a sharp contrast between the economic geographies of right-wing populism in core and peripheral EU member states. We find a strong association between falling behind the richest region of the country and RWPP support within core EU countries, while in peripheral EU states falling behind the EU core is associated with regional support for RWPPs. This suggests that RWPP voters in peripheral countries cue on how they are faring relative to the EU core, while RWPP supporters in core countries cue on how they are faring relative to dynamic regions of their own country. Our analysis also shows that increased manufacturing employment reinforces the effect of falling behind the richest region in core EU member states, while we find no strong evidence that regional economic stagnation is important to the electoral performance of RWPPs.KEYWORDS: Europegeographyinequalityright-wing populism AcknowledgementsAn earlier version of the paper was presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association (Montreal) in September 2022 and at a workshop at Copenhagen Business School in October 2022. We thank the participants in both events for constructive feedback.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 While SD’s national vote share increased by 2.5 points, its Stockholm vote share increased by less than one percentage point. Statistics Sweden, https://www.scb.se/en/finding-statistics/statistics-by-subject-area/democracy/general-elections/general-elections-results/.2 Dropping the three smallest member states (Luxembourg, Cyprus and Malta) and losing some additional observations for lack of data on independent variables, our analysis is restricted to 1,053 regional units in 25 countries. Regional units are NUTS 3 regions for 19 countries and NUTS 2 regions for 6 countries (Belgium, Ireland, Netherlands, Poland, Slovenia and the UK). Countries that have joined the EU since 1990 enter the dataset the year they obtained the status of an ‘accession country.’ The EU-NED dataset and codebook are available at: https://dataverse.harvard.edu/file.xhtml?fileId=6157990&version=1.13 We consider ‘right-wing’ to be interchangeable with ‘far Right’ and ‘radical Right.’ While many recent studies posit common determinants of left-wing and right-wing populism, Gonthier (Citation2023) as well as Burgoon et al. (Citation2019) emphasise differences in the motivations of individuals who support left-wing and right-wing populist parties.4 It goes without saying that there is an important (inter-)subjective component to social status, but social status should not be conflated with the conflicts over cultural values emphasised by Inglehart and Norris (Citation2019). In our understanding, a ‘materialist account’ does not imply that ‘objective conditions’ suffice to explain support for right-wing populist parties. Notable contributions to the literature that link right-wing populism to divergence in regional economic trajectories include Hobolt (Citation2016), McNamara (Citation2017), Rodríguez-Pose (Citation2018), Essletzbichler et al. (Citation2018), Carreras et al. (Citation2019), Djikstra et al. (Citation2019), Schraff (Citation2019) and Adler and Ansell (Citation2020). See Chou et al. (Citation2022) for a broader discussion of the ‘localist turn’ in the study of populism.5 All parties that we identify as ‘right-wing populist’ are also coded by PopuList as ‘Eurosceptic.’ See Djikstra et al. (Citation2019) for a useful discussion of the overlap between populism and Euroskepticism.6 As documented by Hense and Schäfer (Citation2022), perceptions of not having any political voice are closely associated with voting for RWPPs across European democracies. See Lipps and Schraff (Citation2021) on the effects of regional inequality on trust in national political institutions and EU institutions.7 Other studies that identify differences in public attitudes across the divide between rich and poor EU member states include De Vries (Citation2018), Vasilopoulou and Talving (Citation2020), and Mayne and Katsanidou (Citation2022).8 Analyzing party programmes presented in Land elections, León and Scantamburlo (Citation2022) provide a fascinating case study of how the AfD balances efforts to mobilise regional grievances with appeals to German national identity.9 Our argumentation also draws inspiration from Scase (Citation1977). Building on Runciman (Citation1966), Scase shows convincingly that Swedish manual workers are much more likely to compare themselves to (upper) middle-class individuals than their British counterparts. He attributes the difference between his two samples to the structure of national union movements.10 Note that our conceptualisation of the core-periphery distinction is fundamentally economic and thus different from similar distinctions by students of European integration (e.g., Schimmelfennig, Citation2016). Like the empirical analysis that follows, Table 1 excludes the three smallest EU member states. Luxembourg clearly belongs in the EU core by virtue of its GDP per capita ($131,511 in 2021) as well as being a founding member of the EU. The UK features as a core EU member state because our analysis pertains to the period from 1990 to 2018. Note also that all core member states were richer than all peripheral member states already in 1990.11 ARDECO estimates of regional GDP per capita take purchasing power into account. Source: https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/territorial/ardeco-database_en.12 The rise of regional inequality stands in sharp contrast to stability of personal (‘vertical’) income inequality in the EU core since the financial crisis of 2007–2008: averaging across the ten countries, the top 10 per cent share of pre-tax national income increased by less than 1 per cent from 2006 to 2021 (https://wid.world/). The Swedish case illustrates divergent trends in vertical and horizontal inequalities as well as regional variation in right-wing populist support. As defined by Statistics Sweden, the percentage of adults ‘at risk of poverty’ was 14.2 per cent in metropolitan areas and 14.3 per cent in smaller towns and rural areas in 2010. By 2020, the figure for metropolitan areas had dropped to 11.8 per cent while the figure for smaller towns and rural areas had increased to 20.3 per cent (https://www.statistikdatabasen.scb.se/pxweb/en/ssd/START__LE__LE0101/). Over the same period, the overall Gini coefficient for post-tax national income declined from .31 to .29 (https://wid.world/).13 We prefer a fixed effects specification for the region and year levels rather than random effects as standard error estimates are more conservative. Moreover, there currently are no readily available estimation procedures that allow quasi-binomial link functions in multi-level GLM, as well as a lack of tools to calculate clustered standard errors.14 Our measures of the aforementioned control variables are also based on ARDECO data (https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/territorial/ardeco-database_en). See Appendix 1 for descriptive statistics on all variables included in our analysis.15 Note that there are 11 core countries and 14 peripheral ones, and still the N of the core-country sample is 4,888 and the N of the periphery-country sample 2,588. This is due to the fact the data for richer countries covers a longer time period and that richer countries tend to have more regions (e.g., Germany has around 400 NUTS3 regions).16 The interaction effects reported in Table 4 are estimated using standardised variables and a double-demeaned estimator (Giesselmann & Schmidt-Catran, Citation2022).17 The non-linear patterns at high values of GDP growth in the left-hand panel of Figure 7 result from statistical extrapolation, with very few observations driving these results (see rug plot below the marginal effects).Additional informationFundingDominik Schraff’s work on this paper was supported by an Ambizione Grant from the Swiss National Science Foundation (grant number 186002). Jonas Pontusson’s contribution was funded by the European Research Council under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program (Advanced grant number 741538).Notes on contributorsDominik SchraffDominik Schraff is associate professor of political science at Aalborg University, Denmark.Jonas PontussonJonas Pontusson is professor of political science at the University of Geneva, Switzerland.
落后于谁?欧洲右翼民粹主义的经济地理
现有研究表明,右翼民粹主义政党(RWPPs)对物质条件落后的社区人群具有吸引力。然而,当基准社区在政治上变得不满时,它仍然是开放的。我们认为,地域不平等的结构影响了落后地区人们使用的基准。利用1990年至2018年欧盟国家次国家选举结果进行的面板数据回归显示,右翼民粹主义在欧盟核心成员国和外围成员国的经济地理上形成了鲜明对比。我们发现,落后于该国最富裕地区与欧盟核心国家对RWPP的支持之间存在很强的联系,而在欧盟外围国家,落后于欧盟核心与区域对RWPP的支持有关。这表明,边缘国家的RWPP选民取决于他们相对于欧盟核心的表现,而核心国家的RWPP支持者则取决于他们相对于本国充满活力的地区的表现。我们的分析还表明,制造业就业的增加强化了落后于欧盟核心成员国最富裕地区的影响,而我们没有发现强有力的证据表明区域经济停滞对rwpp的选举表现很重要。本文的早期版本于2022年9月在美国政治科学协会(蒙特利尔)年会上发表,并于2022年10月在哥本哈根商学院的研讨会上发表。我们感谢两场活动的参与者提供的建设性反馈。披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。注1虽然瑞典民主党在全国的投票份额增加了2.5个百分点,但其在斯德哥尔摩的投票份额只增加了不到一个百分点。剔除三个最小的成员国(卢森堡、塞浦路斯和马耳他),并因缺乏自变量数据而失去一些额外的观察结果,我们的分析仅限于25个国家的1,053个区域单位。区域单位为19个国家的NUTS 3区域和6个国家(比利时、爱尔兰、荷兰、波兰、斯洛文尼亚和英国)的NUTS 2区域。自1990年以来加入欧盟的国家在获得“加入国”地位的那一年进入该数据集。我们认为“右翼”与“极右翼”和“激进右翼”是可以互换的。虽然最近的许多研究都假设了左翼和右翼民粹主义的共同决定因素,但Gonthier (Citation2023)和Burgoon等人(Citation2019)强调了支持左翼和右翼民粹主义政党的个人动机的差异毋庸置疑,社会地位有一个重要的(相互)主观因素,但社会地位不应与Inglehart和Norris强调的文化价值观冲突混为一谈(Citation2019)。在我们的理解中,“唯物主义解释”并不意味着“客观条件”足以解释对右翼民粹主义政党的支持。将右翼民粹主义与区域经济轨迹分化联系起来的文献中值得注意的贡献包括Hobolt (Citation2016)、McNamara (Citation2017)、Rodríguez-Pose (Citation2018)、Essletzbichler等人(Citation2018)、Carreras等人(Citation2019)、Djikstra等人(Citation2019)、Schraff (Citation2019)和Adler和Ansell (Citation2020)。参见Chou等人(Citation2022)对民粹主义研究中“地方主义转向”的更广泛讨论所有被我们称为“右翼民粹主义”的政党也被民粹主义者称为“欧洲怀疑论者”。参见Djikstra等人(Citation2019)对民粹主义和欧洲怀疑主义之间重叠的有用讨论。6正如Hense和Schäfer (Citation2022)所记录的那样,没有任何政治发言权的观念与欧洲民主国家对rwpp的投票密切相关。参见Lipps和Schraff (Citation2021)关于区域不平等对国家政治机构和欧盟机构信任的影响其他研究确定了贫富欧盟成员国之间公众态度的差异,包括De Vries (Citation2018), Vasilopoulou和Talving (Citation2020),以及Mayne和Katsanidou (Citation2022)León和Scantamburlo (Citation2022)对各州选举中的政党纲领进行了分析,提供了一个引人入胜的案例,研究德国新选择党如何在动员地区不满和呼吁德国民族认同之间取得平衡我们的论证也从Scase (Citation1977)中得到启发。 在Runciman (Citation1966)的基础上,Scase令人信服地表明,瑞典体力劳动者比他们的英国同行更有可能将自己与(上层)中产阶级进行比较。他把两个样本之间的差异归因于国家工会运动的结构请注意,我们对核心-外围区分的概念化从根本上讲是经济的,因此与欧洲一体化学生的类似区分不同(例如,Schimmelfennig, Citation2016)。与接下来的实证分析一样,表1排除了三个最小的欧盟成员国。卢森堡的人均国内生产总值(2021年为131511美元)以及欧盟创始成员国的身份,显然属于欧盟核心。英国是欧盟的核心成员国,因为我们的分析涵盖了1990年至2018年这段时间。还要注意的是,所有核心成员国在1990年就已经比所有外围成员国富裕了。11 ARDECO对地区人均国内生产总值的估计将购买力考虑在内。资料来源:https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/territorial/ardeco-database_en.12自2007-2008年金融危机以来,地区不平等的加剧与欧盟核心国家个人(“垂直”)收入不平等的稳定形成鲜明对比:平均而言,从2006年到2021年,前10%的税前国民收入份额增加了不到1% (https://wid.world/)。瑞典的情况说明了纵向和横向不平等的不同趋势,以及右翼民粹主义支持的地区差异。根据瑞典统计局的定义,2010年,大都市地区“有贫困风险”的成年人比例为14.2%,小城镇和农村地区为14.3%。到2020年,大都市地区的这一数字下降到11.8%,而小城镇和农村地区的这一数字增加到20.3% (https://www.statistikdatabasen.scb.se/pxweb/en/ssd/START__LE__LE0101/)。在同一时期,税后国民收入的基尼系数从0.31下降到0.29 (https://wid.world/).13)由于标准误差估计更为保守,我们更倾向于对地区和年份水平采用固定效应规范,而不是随机效应。此外,目前还没有现成的估计程序,允许准二项式链接函数在多层次GLM中,以及缺乏工具来计算聚类标准误差我们对上述控制变量的测量也是基于ARDECO数据(https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/territorial/ardeco-database_en)。我们的分析中包含的所有变量的描述性统计数据见附录1请注意,有11个核心国家和14个外围国家,核心国家样本的N值仍然是4888,外围国家样本的N值是2588。这是由于富裕国家的数据涵盖的时间较长,而且富裕国家往往有更多的地区(例如,德国有大约400个NUTS3地区)表4中报告的相互作用效应是使用标准化变量和双贬低估计器(Giesselmann & Schmidt-Catran, Citation2022)估计的17图7左侧面板中GDP增长高值时的非线性模式是统计外推的结果,很少有观察结果驱动这些结果(见边际效应下面的地毯图)。dominik Schraff在本文中的工作得到了瑞士国家科学基金会Ambizione基金的支持(资助号186002)。Jonas Pontusson的贡献由欧洲研究理事会在欧盟地平线2020研究和创新计划(高级资助号741538)下资助。作者简介:多米尼克·施拉夫,丹麦奥尔堡大学政治学副教授。Jonas Pontusson是瑞士日内瓦大学的政治学教授。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
8.80
自引率
9.50%
发文量
83
期刊介绍: The primary aim of the Journal of European Public Policy is to provide a comprehensive and definitive source of analytical, theoretical and methodological articles in the field of European public policy. Focusing on the dynamics of public policy in Europe, the journal encourages a wide range of social science approaches, both qualitative and quantitative. JEPP defines European public policy widely and welcomes innovative ideas and approaches. The main areas covered by the Journal are as follows: •Theoretical and methodological approaches to the study of public policy in Europe and elsewhere •National public policy developments and processes in Europe •Comparative studies of public policy within Europe
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信